Tải bản đầy đủ (.pdf) (1 trang)

(8th edition) (the pearson series in economics) robert pindyck, daniel rubinfeld microecon 348

Bạn đang xem bản rút gọn của tài liệu. Xem và tải ngay bản đầy đủ của tài liệu tại đây (144.44 KB, 1 trang )

CHAPTER 9 • The Analysis of Competitive Markets 323

would be -B - C = -1.60 - 4.08 = -$5.68 billion. Note that most of
this deadweight loss is from triangle C, i.e., the loss to those consumers who
are unable to obtain natural gas as a result of the price controls.

20

P= $19.20
Supply

18
Demand
16

PG ($/mcf )

14
12
10
$7.73
8
B
6

C
PO = $6.40

4
2


A
QD = 29.1

QS = 20.6

Pmax = $3.00

0
0

10

20
Quantity (Tcf) Q* = 23

30

40

F IGURE 9.4

EFFECTS OF NATURAL GAS PRICE CONTROLS
The market-clearing price of natural gas was $6.40 per mcf, and the (hypothetical) maximum
allowable price is $3.00. A shortage of 29.1 - 20.6 = 8.5 Tcf results. The gain to consumers
is rectangle A minus triangle B, and the loss to producers is rectangle A plus triangle C. The
deadweight loss is the sum of triangles B plus C.

9.2 The Efficiency of a Competitive Market
To evaluate a market outcome, we often ask whether it achieves economic
efficiency—the maximization of aggregate consumer and producer surplus.

We just saw how price controls create a deadweight loss. The policy therefore
imposes an efficiency cost on the economy: Taken together, producer and consumer surplus are reduced by the amount of the deadweight loss. (Of course,
this does not mean that such a policy is bad; it may achieve other objectives that
policymakers and the public deem important.)
MARKET FAILURE One might think that if the only objective is to achieve
economic efficiency, a competitive market is better left alone. This is sometimes,

• economic efficiency
Maximization of aggregate
consumer and producer surplus.



×