Tải bản đầy đủ (.pdf) (1 trang)

Economic growth and economic development 250

Bạn đang xem bản rút gọn của tài liệu. Xem và tải ngay bản đầy đủ của tài liệu tại đây (164.74 KB, 1 trang )

Introduction to Modern Economic Growth
Definition 5.2. A feasible allocation (x, y) for economy E ≡ (H, F, u, ω, Y, X, θ)

is Pareto optimal if there exists no other feasible allocation (ˆ
x, y
ˆ) such that xˆi ∈ X i ,
yˆf ∈ Y f for all f ∈ F,
X
i∈H

xˆij ≤

X

ωij +

i∈H

X

f ∈F

yˆjf for all j ∈ N,

and
¡ ¢
¡ ¢
ui xˆi ≥ ui xi for all i ∈ H

with at least one strict inequality.


Our next result is the celebrated First Welfare Theorem for competitive economies.
Before presenting this result, we need the following definition.
Definition 5.3. Household i ∈ H is locally non-satiated at xi if ui (xi ) is

strictly increasing in at least one of its arguments at xi and ui (xi ) < ∞.

The latter requirement in this definition is already implied by the fact that
ui : X i → R, but it is included for additional emphasis, since it is important for the

proof and also because if in fact we had ui (xi ) = ∞, we could not meaningfully talk

about ui (xi ) being strictly increasing.

Theorem 5.5. (First Welfare Theorem I) Suppose that (x∗ , y∗ , p∗ ) is a
competitive equilibrium of economy E ≡ (H, F, u, ω, Y, X, θ) with H finite. Assume

that all households are locally non-satiated at x∗ . Then (x∗ , y∗ ) is Pareto optimal.

Proof. To obtain a contradiction, suppose that there exists a feasible (ˆ
x, y
ˆ)
xi ) ≥ ui (xi ) for all i ∈ H and ui (ˆ
xi ) > ui (xi ) for all i ∈ H0 , where H0
such that ui (ˆ
is a non-empty subset of H.

Since (x∗ , y∗ , p∗ ) is a competitive equilibrium, it must be the case that for all

i ∈ H,
(5.13)


p∗ ·ˆ
xi ≥ p∗ · xi∗
Ã
= p∗ ·

ωi +

236

X

f ∈F

θif y f ∗

!



×