Tải bản đầy đủ (.pdf) (1 trang)

Economic growth and economic development 300

Bạn đang xem bản rút gọn của tài liệu. Xem và tải ngay bản đầy đủ của tài liệu tại đây (99.61 KB, 1 trang )

Introduction to Modern Economic Growth
Thus using the notation y = π (x) and combining these two equations, we have
α [π (x)]α−1
1

for all x,
xα − π (x)
[π (x)]α − π (π (x))

which is a functional equation in a single function, π (x). There are no straightforward ways of solving functional equations, but in most cases guess-and-verify type
methods are most fruitful. For example in this case, let us conjecture that
(6.27)

π (x) = axα .

Substituting for this in the previous expression, we obtain
1
αaα−1 xα(α−1)
=
β
,
xα − axα
aα xα2 − a1+α xα2
β
α
=
,
α
a x − axα
which implies that, with the policy function (6.28), a = βα satisfies this equation.
Recall from Corollary 6.1 that, under the assumptions here, there is a unique policy


function. Since we have established that the function
π (x) = βαxα
satisfies the necessary and sufficient conditions (Theorem 6.10), it must be the
unique policy function. This implies that the law of motion of the capital stock
is
(6.28)

k (t + 1) = βα [k (t)]α

and the optimal consumption level is
c (t) = [1 − βa] [k (t)]α .
Exercise 6.7 continues with some of the details of this example, and also shows how
the optimal growth equilibrium involves a sequence of capital-labor ratios converging
to a unique steady state.
Finally, we now have a brief look at the intertemporal utility maximization
problem of a consumer facing a certain income sequence.
Example 6.5. Consider the problem of an infinitely-lived consumer with instantaneous utility function defined over consumption u (c), where u : R+ → R is strictly
increasing, continuously differentiable and strictly concave. The individual discounts
286



×