Tải bản đầy đủ (.pdf) (1 trang)

Economic growth and economic development 357

Bạn đang xem bản rút gọn của tài liệu. Xem và tải ngay bản đầy đủ của tài liệu tại đây (95.2 KB, 1 trang )

Introduction to Modern Economic Growth
above, a natural conjecture might be that, as in the finite-horizon case, the transversality condition should be similar to that in Theorem 7.1, with t1 replaced with the
limit of t → ∞, that is, limt→∞ λ (t) = 0. The following example, which is very

close to the original Ramsey model, illustrates that this is not the case; without further assumptions, the valid transversality condition is given by the weaker condition
(7.39).
Example 7.2. Consider the following problem:
Z ∞
[log (c (t)) − log c∗ ] dt
max
0

subject to

k˙ (t) = [k (t)]α − c (t) − δk (t)
k (0) = 1
and
lim k (t) ≥ 0

t→∞

where c∗ ≡ [k∗ ]α − δk∗ and k∗ ≡ (α/δ)1/(1−α) . In other words, c∗ is the maximum
level of consumption that can be achieved in the steady state of this model and k∗

is the corresponding steady-state level of capital. This way of writing the objective
function makes sure that the integral converges and takes a finite value (since c (t)
cannot exceed c∗ forever).
The Hamiltonian is straightforward to construct; it does not explicitly depend
on time and takes the form
H (k, c, λ) = [log c (t) − log c∗ ] + λ [k (t)α − c (t) − δk (t)] ,
and implies the following necessary conditions (dropping time dependence to simplify the notation):


1
− λ (t) = 0
c (t)
¡
¢
Hk (k, c, λ) = λ (t) αk (t)α−1 − δ = −λ˙ (t) .
Hc (k, c, λ) =

It can be verified that any optimal path must feature c (t) → c∗ as t → ∞. This,
however, implies that

lim λ (t) =

t→∞

1
> 0 and lim k (t) = k∗ .
t→∞
c∗
343



×