Tải bản đầy đủ (.pdf) (1 trang)

Economic growth and economic development 359

Bạn đang xem bản rút gọn của tài liệu. Xem và tải ngay bản đầy đủ của tài liệu tại đây (144.45 KB, 1 trang )

Introduction to Modern Economic Growth
7.5. Discounted Infinite-Horizon Optimal Control
Part of the difficulty, especially regarding the absence of a transversality condition, comes from the fact that we did not impose enough structure on the functions
f and g. As discussed above, our interest is with the growth models where the utility
is discounted exponentially. Consequently, economically interesting problems often
take the following more specific form:
Z ∞
exp (−ρt) f (x (t) , y (t)) dt with ρ > 0,
(7.46)
max W (x (t) , y (t)) ≡
x(t),y(t)

0

subject to
(7.47)

x˙ (t) = g (x (t) , y (t)) ,

and
(7.48)

y (t) ∈ R for all t, x (0) = x0 and lim x (t) ≥ x1 .
t→∞

Notice that throughout we assume ρ > 0, so that there is indeed discounting.
The special feature of this problem is that the objective function, f , depends on
time only through exponential discounting, while the constraint equation, g, is not
a function of time directly. The Hamiltonian in this case would be:
H (t, x (t) , y (t) , λ (t)) = exp (−ρt) f (x (t) , y (t)) + λ (t) g (x (t) , y (t))
= exp (−ρt) [f (x (t) , y (t)) + µ (t) g (x (t) , y (t))] ,


where the second line defines
µ (t) ≡ exp (ρt) λ (t) .

(7.49)

This equation makes it clear that the Hamiltonian depends on time explicitly only
through the exp (−ρt) term.
In fact, in this case, rather than working with the standard Hamiltonian, we can
work with the current-value Hamiltonian, defined as
(7.50)

ˆ (x (t) , y (t) , µ (t)) ≡ f (x (t) , y (t)) + µ (t) g (x (t) , y (t))
H

which is “autonomous” in the sense that it does not directly depend on time.
The following result establishes the necessity of a stronger transversality condition under some additional assumptions, which are typically met in economic
applications. In preparation for this result, let us refer to the functions f (x, y) and
345



×