Bạn đang xem bản rút gọn của tài liệu. Xem và tải ngay bản đầy đủ của tài liệu tại đây (81.99 KB, 1 trang )
302 PART 2 • Producers, Consumers, and Competitive Markets
for example, that the firm uses labor and capital inputs; its capital equipment
has been purchased. Accounting profit will equal revenues R minus labor cost
wL, which is positive. Economic profit p, however, equals revenues R minus
labor cost wL minus the capital cost, rK:
p = R - wL - rK
As we explained in Chapter 7, the correct measure of capital cost is the user
cost of capital, which is the annual return that the firm could earn by investing
its money elsewhere instead of purchasing capital, plus the annual depreciation
on the capital.
• zero economic profit
A firm is earning a normal
return on its investment—i.e.,
it is doing as well as it could by
investing its money elsewhere.
ZERO ECONOMIC PROFIT When a firm goes into a business, it does so in
the expectation that it will earn a return on its investment. A zero economic
profit means that the firm is earning a normal—i.e., competitive—return on that
investment. This normal return, which is part of the user cost of capital, is the
firm’s opportunity cost of using its money to buy capital rather than investing it
elsewhere. Thus, a firm earning zero economic profit is doing as well by investing its
money in capital as it could by investing elsewhere—it is earning a competitive return
on its money. Such a firm, therefore, is performing adequately and should stay
in business. (A firm earning a negative economic profit, however, should consider
going out of business if it does not expect to improve its financial picture.)
As we will see, in competitive markets economic profit becomes zero in the
long run. Zero economic profit signifies not that firms are performing poorly,
but rather that the industry is competitive.
ENTRY AND EXIT Figure 8.13 shows how a $40 price induces a firm to increase