Bạn đang xem bản rút gọn của tài liệu. Xem và tải ngay bản đầy đủ của tài liệu tại đây (41.53 KB, 1 trang )
648
PA R T V I I Monetary Theory
This example shows how easy it is to misinterpret timing relationships.
Furthermore, by searching for what we hope to find, we might focus on a variable, such as a growth rate, rather than a level, which suggests a misleading relationship. Timing evidence can be a dangerous tool for deciding on causation.
Stated even more forcefully, one person s lead is another person s lag. For
example, you could just as easily interpret the relationship of money growth and
output in Figure 25-2 to say that the money growth rate lags output by three
years after all, the peaks in the money growth series occur three years after the
peaks in the output series. In short, you could say that output leads money growth.
We have seen that timing evidence is extremely hard to interpret. Unless we
can be sure that changes in the leading variable are exogenous events, we cannot
be sure that the leading variable is actually causing the following variable. And it
is all too easy to find what we seek when looking for timing evidence. Perhaps
the best way of describing this danger is to say, timing evidence may be in the
eyes of the beholder.
Monetarist statistical evidence examined the correlations
between money and aggregate output or aggregate spending by performing formal
statistical tests. Again in 1963 (obviously a vintage year for the monetarists), Milton
Friedman and David Meiselman published a paper that proposed the following test
of a monetarist model against a model used by early Keynesians.5 In the Keynesian
framework, investment and government spending were sources of fluctuations
in aggregate demand, so Friedman and Meiselman constructed a Keynesian
autonomous expenditure variable A equal to investment spending plus government
spending. They characterized the Keynesian model as saying that A should be
highly correlated with aggregate spending Y, while the money supply M should not.
In the monetarist model, the money supply is the source of fluctuations in aggregate spending, and M should be highly correlated with Y, while A should not.
A logical way to find out which model is better would be to see which is more
highly correlated with Y: M or A. When Friedman and Meiselman conducted this
test for many different periods of U.S. data, they discovered that the monetarist
model wins!6 They concluded that monetarist analysis gives a better description