Tải bản đầy đủ (.pdf) (80 trang)

essentials of investments with s p bind in card phần 10 potx

Bạn đang xem bản rút gọn của tài liệu. Xem và tải ngay bản đầy đủ của tài liệu tại đây (1.1 MB, 80 trang )

Bodie−Kane−Marcus:
Essentials of Investments,
Fifth Edition
VI. Active Investment
Management
20. Performance Evaluation
and Active Portfolio
Management
© The McGraw−Hill
Companies, 2003
where E(r
M
) Ϫ r
f
is the risk premium on M, and ␴
M
is the standard deviation of M. To make a
rational allocation of funds requires an estimate of ␴
M
and E(r
M
), so even a passive investor
needs to do some forecasting.
Forecasting E(r
M
) and ␴
M
is complicated further because security classes are affected
by different environment factors. Long-term bond returns, for example, are driven largely by
changes in the term structure of interest rates, while returns on equity depend also on changes
in the broader economic environment, including macroeconomic factors besides interest rates.


Once you begin considering how economic conditions influence separate sorts of investments,
you might as well use a sophisticated asset allocation program to determine the proper mix for
the portfolio. It is easy to see how investors get lured away from a purely passive strategy.
Even the definition of a “pure” passive strategy is not very clear-cut, as simple strategies
involving only the market index portfolio and risk-free assets now seem to call for market
analysis. Our strict definition of a pure passive strategy is one that invests only in index funds
and weights those funds by fixed proportions that do not change in response to market condi-
tions: a portfolio strategy that always places 60% in a stock market index fund, 30% in a bond
index fund, and 10% in a money market fund, regardless of expectations.
Active management is attractive because the potential profit is enormous, even though
competition among managers is bound to drive market prices to near-efficient levels. For
prices to remain efficient to some degree, decent profits to diligent analysts must be the rule
rather than the exception, although large profits may be difficult to earn. Absence of profits
would drive people out of the investment management industry, resulting in prices moving
away from informationally efficient levels.
Objectives of Active Portfolios
What does an investor expect from a professional portfolio manager, and how do these ex-
pectations affect the manager’s response? If all clients were risk neutral (indifferent to risk),
the answer would be straightforward: The investment manager should construct a portfolio
with the highest possible expected rate of return, and the manager should then be judged by
the realized average rate of return.
When the client is risk averse, the answer is more difficult. Lacking standards to proceed
by, the manager would have to consult with each client before making any portfolio decision
in order to ascertain that the prospective reward (average return) matched the client’s attitude
toward risk. Massive, continuous client input would be needed, and the economic value of
professional management would be questionable.
Fortunately, the theory of mean-variance efficiency allows us to separate the “product deci-
sion,” which is how to construct a mean-variance efficient risky portfolio, from the “con-
sumption decision,” which describes the investor’s allocation of funds between the efficient
risky portfolio and the safe asset. You have learned already that construction of the optimal

risky portfolio is purely a technical problem and that there is a single optimal risky portfolio
appropriate for all investors. Investors differ only in how they apportion investment between
that risky portfolio and the safe asset.
The mean-variance theory also speaks to performance in offering a criterion for judging
managers on their choice of risky portfolios. In Chapter 6, we established that the optimal
risky portfolio is the one that maximizes the reward-to-variability ratio, that is, the expected
excess return divided by the standard deviation. A manager who maximizes this ratio will sat-
isfy all clients regardless of risk aversion.
Clients can evaluate managers using statistical methods to draw inferences from realized
rates of return about prospective, or ex ante, reward-to-variability ratios. The Sharpe measure,
20 Performance Evaluation and Active Portfolio Management 701
Bodie−Kane−Marcus:
Essentials of Investments,
Fifth Edition
VI. Active Investment
Management
20. Performance Evaluation
and Active Portfolio
Management
© The McGraw−Hill
Companies, 2003
or the equivalent M
2
, is now a widely accepted way to track performance of professionally
managed portfolios:
S
P
ϭ
The most able manager will be the one who consistently obtains the highest Sharpe meas-
ure, implying that the manager has real forecasting ability. A client’s judgment of a manager’s

ability will affect the fraction of investment funds allocated to this manager; the client can in-
vest the remainder with competing managers and in a safe fund.
If managers’ Sharpe measures were reasonably constant over time, and clients could reli-
ably estimate them, allocating funds to managers would be an easy decision.
Actually, the use of the Sharpe measure as the prime measure of a manager’s ability re-
quires some qualification. We know from the discussion of performance evaluation earlier in
this chapter that the Sharpe ratio is the appropriate measure of performance only when the
client’s entire wealth is managed by the professional investor. Moreover, clients may impose
additional restrictions on portfolio choice that further complicate the performance evaluation
problem.
20.4 MARKET TIMING
Consider the results of three different investment strategies, as gleaned from Table 5.3:
1. Investor X, who put $1 in 30 day T-bills (or their predecessors) on January 1, 1926, and
always rolled over all proceeds into 30-day T-bills, would have ended on December 31,
2001, 76 years later, with $16.98.
2. Investor Y, who put $1 in large stocks (the S&P 500 portfolio) on January 1, 1926,
and reinvested all dividends in that portfolio, would have ended on December 31, 2001,
with $1,987.01.
3. Suppose we define perfect market timing as the ability to tell with certainty at the
beginning of each year whether stocks will outperform bills. Investor Z, the perfect timer,
shifts all funds at the beginning of each year into either bills or stocks, whichever is
going to do better. Beginning at the same date, how much would Investor Z have ended
up with 76 years later? Answer: $115,233.89!
3. What are the annually compounded rates of return for the X, Y, and perfect-timing
strategies over the period 1926–2001?
These results have some lessons for us. The first has to do with the power of compounding.
Its effect is particularly important as more and more of the funds under management represent
pension savings. The horizons of pension investments may not be as long as 76 years, but they
are measured in decades, making compounding a significant factor.
The second is a huge difference between the end value of the all-safe asset strategy

($16.98) and of the all-equity strategy ($1,987.01). Why would anyone invest in safe assets
given this historical record? If you have absorbed all the lessons of this book, you know the
reason: risk. The averages of the annual rates of return and the standard deviations on the all-
bills and all-equity strategies were
Arithmetic Mean Standard Deviation
Bills 3.85% 3.25%
Equities 12.49 20.30
E(r
P
) Ϫ r
f

P
702 Part SIX Active Investment Management
market timing
Asset allocation in
which the investment
in the market is
increased if one
forecasts that
the market will
outperform bills.
Concept
CHECK
>
Bodie−Kane−Marcus:
Essentials of Investments,
Fifth Edition
VI. Active Investment
Management

20. Performance Evaluation
and Active Portfolio
Management
© The McGraw−Hill
Companies, 2003
The significantly higher standard deviation of the rate of return on the equity portfolio is
commensurate with its significantly higher average return. The higher average return reflects
the risk premium.
Is the return premium on the perfect-timing strategy a risk premium? Because the perfect
timer never does worse than either bills or the market, the extra return cannot be compensa-
tion for the possibility of poor returns; instead it is attributable to superior analysis. The value
of superior information is reflected in the tremendous ending value of the portfolio. This value
does not reflect compensation for risk.
To see why, consider how you might choose between two hypothetical strategies. Strat-
egy 1 offers a sure rate of return of 5%; strategy 2 offers an uncertain return that is given by
5% plus a random number that is zero with a probability of 0.5 and 5% with a probability of
0.5. The results for each strategy are
Strategy 1 (%) Strategy 2 (%)
Expected return 5 7.5
Standard deviation 0 2.5
Highest return 5 10
Lowest return 5 5
Clearly, strategy 2 dominates strategy 1, as its rate of return is at least equal to that of strat-
egy 1 and sometimes greater. No matter how risk averse you are, you will always prefer strat-
egy 2 to strategy 1, even though strategy 2 has a significant standard deviation. Compared to
strategy 1, strategy 2 provides only good surprises, so the standard deviation in this case can-
not be a measure of risk.
You can look at these strategies as analogous to the case of the perfect timer compared with
either an all-equity or all-bills strategy. In every period, the perfect timer obtains at least as
good a return, in some cases better. Therefore, the timer’s standard deviation is a misleading

measure of risk when you compare perfect timing to an all-equity or all-bills strategy.
Valuing Market Timing as an Option
Merton (1981) shows that the key to analyzing the pattern of returns of a perfect market timer
is to compare the returns of a perfect foresight investor with those of another investor who
holds a call option on the equity portfolio. Investing 100% in bills plus holding a call option
on the equity portfolio will yield returns identical to those of the portfolio of the perfect timer
who invests 100% in either the safe asset or the equity portfolio, whichever will yield the
higher return. The perfect timer’s return is shown in Figure 20.5. The rate of return is bounded
from below by the risk-free rate, r
f
.
To see how the value of information can be treated as an option, suppose the market index
currently is at S
0
and a call option on the index has exercise price of X ϭ S
0
(1 ϩ r
f
). If the
market outperforms bills over the coming period, S
T
will exceed X; it will be less than X other-
wise. Now look at the payoff to a portfolio consisting of this option and S
0
dollars invested
in bills.
Payoff to Portfolio
Outcome: S
T
Յ XS

T
Ͼ X
Bills S
0
(1 ϩ r
f
) S
0
(1 ϩ r
f
)
Option 0 S
T
Ϫ X
Total S
0
(1 ϩ r
f
) S
T
20 Performance Evaluation and Active Portfolio Management 703
Bodie−Kane−Marcus:
Essentials of Investments,
Fifth Edition
VI. Active Investment
Management
20. Performance Evaluation
and Active Portfolio
Management
© The McGraw−Hill

Companies, 2003
The portfolio returns the risk-free rate when the market is bearish (that is, when the market
return is less than the risk-free rate) and pays the market return when the market is bullish and
beats bills. This represents perfect market timing. Consequently, the value of perfect timing
ability is equivalent to the value of the call option, for a call enables the investor to earn the
market return only when it exceeds r
f
.
Valuation of the call option embedded in market timing is relatively straightforward using
the Black-Scholes formula. Set S ϭ $1 (to find the value of the call per dollar invested in the
market), use an exercise price of X ϭ (1 ϩ r
f
) (the current risk-free rate is about 3%), and
a volatility of ␴ϭ.203 (the historical volatility of the S&P 500). For a once-a-year timer,
T ϭ 1 year. According to the Black-Scholes formula, the call option conveyed by market tim-
ing ability is worth about 8.1% of assets, and this is the annual fee one could presumably
charge for such services. More frequent timing would be worth more. If one could time
the market on a monthly basis, then T ϭ
1
⁄12 and the value of perfect timing would be 2.3%
per month.
The Value of Imperfect Forecasting
But managers are not perfect forecasters. While managers who are right most of the time
presumably do very well, “right most of the time” does not mean merely the percentage of the
time a manager is right. For example, a Tucson, Arizona, weather forecaster who always
predicts “no rain” may be right 90% of the time, but this “stopped clock” strategy does not
require any forecasting ability.
Neither is the overall proportion of correct forecasts an appropriate measure of market
forecasting ability. If the market is up two days out of three, and a forecaster always predicts
a market advance, the two-thirds success rate is not a measure of forecasting ability. We need

to examine the proportion of bull markets (r
M
Ͼ r
f
) correctly forecast and the proportion of
bear markets (r
M
Ͻ r
f
) correctly forecast.
If we call P
1
the proportion of the correct forecasts of bull markets and P
2
the proportion
for bear markets, then P
1
ϩ P
2
Ϫ 1 is the correct measure of timing ability. For example, a
forecaster who always guesses correctly will have P
1
ϭ P
2
ϭ 1 and will show ability of 1
(100%). An analyst who always bets on a bear market will mispredict all bull markets
(P
1
ϭ 0), will correctly “predict” all bear markets (P
2

ϭ 1), and will end up with timing
ability of P
1
ϩ P
2
Ϫ 1 ϭ 0. If C denotes the (call option) value of a perfect market timer, then
(P
1
ϩ P
2
Ϫ 1)C measures the value of imperfect forecasting ability.
704
Part SIX Active Investment Management
FIGURE 20.5
Rate of return of a
perfect market time
r
f
r
f
r
M
Rate of return
Bodie−Kane−Marcus:
Essentials of Investments,
Fifth Edition
VI. Active Investment
Management
20. Performance Evaluation
and Active Portfolio

Management
© The McGraw−Hill
Companies, 2003
The incredible potential payoff to accurate timing versus the relative scarcity of billionaires
should suggest to you that market timing is far from a trivial exercise and that very imperfect
timing is the most that we can hope for.
4. What is the market timing score of someone who flips a fair coin to predict the
market?
Measurement of Market Timing Performance
In its pure form, market timing involves shifting funds between a market index portfolio and
a safe asset, such as T-bills or a money market fund, depending on whether the market as a
whole is expected to outperform the safe asset. In practice, most managers do not shift fully
between bills and the market. How might we measure partial shifts into the market when it is
expected to perform well?
To simplify, suppose the investor holds only the market index portfolio and T-bills. If the
weight on the market were constant, say 0.6, then the portfolio beta would also be constant,
and the portfolio characteristic line would plot as a straight line with a slope 0.6, as in Figure
20.6A. If, however, the investor could correctly time the market and shift funds into it in peri-
ods when the market does well, the characteristic line would plot as in Figure 20.6B. The idea
is that if the timer can predict bull and bear markets, more will be shifted into the market when
the market is about to go up. The portfolio beta and the slope of the characteristic line will be
higher when r
M
is higher, resulting in the curved line that appears in 20.6B.
Treynor and Mazuy (1966) tested to see whether portfolio betas did in fact increase prior
to market advances, but they found little evidence of timing ability. A similar test was imple-
mented by Henriksson (1984). His examination of market timing ability for 116 funds in
20 Performance Evaluation and Active Portfolio Management 705
Concept
CHECK

<
FIGURE 20.6
Characteristic lines
A: No market timing,
beta is constant
B: Market timing,
beta increases with
expected market
excess return
Steadily
increasing
slope
r
P
– r
f
r
M
– r
f
Slope = 0.6
r
P
– r
f
r
M
– r
f
A. No Market Timing, Beta Is Constant

B. Market Timing, Beta Increases with Expected Market
Excess Return
Bodie−Kane−Marcus:
Essentials of Investments,
Fifth Edition
VI. Active Investment
Management
20. Performance Evaluation
and Active Portfolio
Management
© The McGraw−Hill
Companies, 2003
1968–1980 found that, on average, portfolio betas actually fell slightly during the market ad-
vances, although in most cases the response of portfolio betas to the market was not statisti-
cally significant. Eleven funds had statistically positive values of market timing, while eight
had significantly negative values. Overall, 62% of the funds had negative point estimates of
timing ability.
In sum, empirical tests to date show little evidence of market timing ability. Perhaps this
should be expected; given the tremendous values to be reaped by a successful market timer, it
would be surprising to uncover clear-cut evidence of such skills in nearly efficient markets.
20.5 STYLE ANALYSIS
Style analysis was introduced by Nobel laureate William Sharpe.
3
The popularity of the con-
cept was aided by a well-known study
4
concluding that 91.5% of the variation in returns of
82 mutual funds could be explained by the funds’ asset allocation to bills, bonds, and stocks.
Later studies that considered asset allocation across a broader range of asset classes found that
as much as 97% of fund returns can be explained by asset allocation alone.

Sharpe considered 12 asset class (style) portfolios. His idea was to regress fund returns on
indexes representing a range of asset classes. The regression coefficient on each index would
then measure the implicit allocation to that “style.” Because funds are barred from short posi-
tions, the regression coefficients are constrained to be either zero or positive and to sum to
100%, so as to represent a complete asset allocation. The R-square of the regression would
then measure the percentage of return variability attributed to the effects of security selection.
To illustrate the approach, consider Sharpe’s study of the monthly returns on Fidelity’s
Magellan Fund over the period January 1985 through December 1989, shown in Table 20.7.
706 Part SIX Active Investment Management
TABLE 20.7
Sharpe’s style
portfolios for the
Magellan fund
Regression
Coefficient*
Bills 0
Intermediate bonds 0
Long-term bonds 0
Corporate bonds 0
Mortgages 0
Value stocks 0
Growth stocks 47
Medium-cap stocks 31
Small stocks 18
Foreign stocks 0
European stocks 4
Japanese stocks 0
Total 100.00
R-squared 97.3
*Regressions are constrained to have nonnegative coefficients and to have coefficients

that sum to 100%.
Source: William F. Sharpe, “Asset Allocation: Management Style and Performance
Evaluation,” Journal of Portfolio Management, Winter 1992, pp. 7–19.
3
William F. Sharpe, “Asset Allocation: Management Style and Performance Evaluation,” Journal of Portfolio Man-
agement, Winter 1992, pp. 7–19.
4
Gary Brinson, Brian Singer, and Gilbert Beebower, “Determinants of Portfolio Performance,” Financial Analysts
Journal, May/June 1991.
Bodie−Kane−Marcus:
Essentials of Investments,
Fifth Edition
VI. Active Investment
Management
20. Performance Evaluation
and Active Portfolio
Management
© The McGraw−Hill
Companies, 2003
While there are 12 asset classes, each one represented by a stock index, the regression
coefficients are positive for only 4 of them. We can conclude that the fund returns are well
explained by only four style portfolios. Moreover, these three style portfolios alone explain
97.3% of returns.
The proportion of return variability not explained by asset allocation can be attributed to
security selection within asset classes. For Magellan, this was 100 Ϫ 97.3 ϭ 2.7%. To evalu-
ate the average contribution of stock selection to fund performance we track the residuals from
the regression, displayed in Figure 20.7. The figure plots the cumulative effect of these resid-
uals; the steady upward trend confirms Magellan’s success at stock selection in this period.
Notice that the plot in Figure 20.7 is far smoother than the plot in Figure 20.8, which shows
Magellan’s performance compared to a standard benchmark, the S&P 500. This reflects the

fact that the regression-weighted index portfolio tracks Magellan’s overall style much better
than the S&P 500. The performance spread is much noisier using the S&P as the benchmark.
Of course, Magellan’s consistently positive residual returns (reflected in the steadily
increasing plot of cumulative return difference) is hardly common. Figure 20.9 shows the
20 Performance Evaluation and Active Portfolio Management 707
FIGURE 20.7
Fidelity Magellan
Fund cumulative
return difference:
fund versus style
benchmark
Source: William F. Sharpe,
“Asset Allocation:
Management Style and
Performance Evaluation,”
Journal of Portfolio
Management, Winter 1992,
pp. 7–19.
1986 1987 1988 1989 1990
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
FIGURE 20.8
Fidelity Magellan
Fund cumulative
return difference:

fund versus S&P 500
Source: William F. Sharpe,
“Asset Allocation:
Management Style and
Performance Evaluation,”
Journal of Portfolio
Management, Winter 1992,
pp. 7–19.
1986 1987 1988 1989 1990
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
Ϫ2
Bodie−Kane−Marcus:
Essentials of Investments,
Fifth Edition
VI. Active Investment
Management
20. Performance Evaluation
and Active Portfolio
Management
© The McGraw−Hill
Companies, 2003
frequency distribution of average residuals across 636 mutual funds. The distribution has the
familiar bell shape with a slightly negative mean of Ϫ.074% per month.
Style analysis has become very popular in the investment management industry and has

spawned quite a few variations on Sharpe’s methodology. Many portfolio managers utilize
websites that help investors identify their style and stock selection performance.
20.6 MORNINGSTAR’S RISK-ADJUSTED RATING
The commercial success of Morningstar, Inc., the premier source of information on mutual
funds, has made its Risk Adjusted Rating (RAR) among the most widely used performance
measures. The Morningstar five-star rating is coveted by the managers of the thousands of
funds covered by the service.
Morningstar calculates a number of RAR performance measures that are similar, although
not identical, to the standard mean-variance measures. The most distinct measure, the Morn-
ingstar Star Rating, is based on comparison of each fund to a peer group. The peer group for
each fund is selected on the basis of the fund’s investment universe (e.g., international, growth
versus value, fixed-income, and so on) as well as portfolio characteristics such as average
price-to-book value, price-earnings ratio, and market capitalization.
Morningstar computes fund returns (adjusted for loads) as well as a risk measure based on
fund performance in its worst years. The risk-adjusted performance is ranked across funds in
a style group and stars are awarded based on the following table:
Percentile Stars
0–10 1
10–32.5 2
32.5–67.5 3
67.5–90 4
90–100 5
708 Part SIX Active Investment Management
FIGURE 20.9
Average tracking error,
636 mutual funds,
1985–1989
Source: William F. Sharpe,
“Asset Allocation:
Management Style and

Performance Evaluation,”
Journal of Portfolio
Management, Winter 1992,
pp. 7–19.
Ϫ1.00
Ϫ0.50
0.00
0.50
1.00
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
Average tracking error (%/month)
Bodie−Kane−Marcus:
Essentials of Investments,
Fifth Edition
VI. Active Investment
Management
20. Performance Evaluation
and Active Portfolio
Management
© The McGraw−Hill
Companies, 2003

The Morningstar RAR method produces results that are similar but not identical to that of
the mean/variance-based Sharpe ratios. Figure 20.10 demonstrates the fit between ranking by
RAR and by Sharpe ratios from the performance of 1,286 diversified equity funds over the pe-
riod 1994–1996. Sharpe notes that this period is characterized by high returns that contribute
to a good fit.
20.7 SECURITY SELECTION:
THE TREYNOR-BLACK MODEL
Overview of the Treynor-Black Model
Security analysis is the other dimension of active investment besides timing the overall mar-
ket and asset allocation. Suppose you are an analyst studying individual securities. Quite
likely, you will turn up several securities that appear to be mispriced and offer positive alphas.
But how do you exploit your analysis? Concentrating a portfolio on these securities entails a
cost, namely, the firm-specific risk you could shed by more fully diversifying. As an active
manager, you must strike a balance between aggressive exploitation of security mispricing and
diversification considerations that dictate against concentrating a portfolio in a few stocks.
Jack Treynor and Fischer Black (1973) developed a portfolio construction model for man-
agers who use security analysis. It assumes security markets are nearly efficient. The essence
of the model is this:
1. Security analysts in an active investment management organization can analyze in depth
only a relatively small number of stocks out of the entire universe of securities. The
securities not analyzed are assumed to be fairly priced.
2. For the purpose of efficient diversification, the market index portfolio is the baseline
portfolio, which is treated as the passive portfolio.
3. The macro forecasting unit of the investment management firm provides forecasts of
the expected rate of return and variance of the passive (market index) portfolio.
4. The objective of security analysis is to form an active portfolio of a necessarily limited
number of securities. Perceived mispricing of the analyzed securities is what determines
the composition of this active portfolio.
20 Performance Evaluation and Active Portfolio Management 709
FIGURE 20.10

Rankings based on
Morningstar’s category
RARs and excess return
Sharpe ratios
Source: William F. Sharpe,
“Morningstar
Performance Measures,”
www.wsharpe.com.
0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1
1
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
Sharpe ratio
percentile in category
Category RAR
percentile in
category
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩϩ
ϩϩ
ϩ
ϩϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ

ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
ϩ
Bodie−Kane−Marcus:
Essentials of Investments,
Fifth Edition
VI. Active Investment
Management
20. Performance Evaluation
and Active Portfolio
Management
© The McGraw−Hill
Companies, 2003
5. Analysts follow several steps to make up the active portfolio and forecast its
performance:
a. Estimate the characteristic line of each analyzed security and obtain its beta and
residual variance. From the beta and the macro forecast, E(r
M

) Ϫ r
f
, determine
the required rate of return of the security.
b. Determine the expected return. Subtracting the required return yields the expected
abnormal return (alpha) of the security.
c. Use the estimates for the values of alpha, beta, and residual risk to determine the
optimal weight of each security in the active portfolio.
d. Estimate the alpha, beta, and residual variance for the active portfolio according to
the weights of the securities in the portfolio.
6. The macroeconomic forecasts for the passive index portfolio and the composite forecast
for the active portfolio are used to determine the optimal risky portfolio, which will be
a combination of the passive and active portfolios.
Although some sophisticated investment managers use the Treynor-Black model, it has
not taken the industry by storm. This is unfortunate for several reasons:
1. Just as even imperfect market-timing ability has enormous value, security analysis of the
sort Treynor and Black propose has similar potential value. Even with far-from-perfect
security analysis, active management can add value.
2. The Treynor-Black model is easy to implement. Moreover, it is useful even relaxing
some of its simplifying assumptions.
3. The model lends itself to use with decentralized decision making, which is essential to
efficiency in complex organizations.
Portfolio Construction
Assuming all securities are fairly priced and using the index model as a guideline for the rate
of return on securities, the rate of return on security i is given by
r
i
ϭ r
f
ϩ␤

i
(r
M
Ϫ r
f
) ϩ e
i
(20.1)
where e
i
is the zero mean, firm-specific (nonsystematic) component.
Absent security analysis, Treynor and Black take Equation 20.1 to represent the rate of re-
turn on all securities and assume the index portfolio (M) is efficient. For simplicity, they also
assume the nonsystematic components of returns, e
i
, are independent across securities. Mar-
ket timing is incorporated in the terms r
M
and ␴
M
, representing index portfolio forecasts. The
overall investment in the risky portfolio will be affected by the optimism or pessimism re-
flected in these numbers.
Assume a team of security analysts investigates a subset of the universe of available secu-
rities, with the objective of forming an active portfolio. That portfolio will then be mixed with
the index portfolio to improve diversification. For each security, k, that is researched, we write
the rate of return as
r
k
ϭ r

f
ϩ␤
k
(r
M
Ϫ r
f
) ϩ e
k
ϩ␣
k
(20.2)
where ␣
k
represents the extra (abnormal) expected return attributable to the mispricing of the
security. Thus, for each security analyzed, the research team estimates the parameters

k
, ␤
k
, ␴
2
(e
k
)
If all the ␣
k
turn out to be zero, there would be no reason to depart from the passive
strategy, and the index portfolio would remain the manager’s choice. But this is a remote
710 Part SIX Active Investment Management

Treynor-Black
model
An optimizing
model for portfolio
managers who use
security analysis in a
nearly efficient
market.
Bodie−Kane−Marcus:
Essentials of Investments,
Fifth Edition
VI. Active Investment
Management
20. Performance Evaluation
and Active Portfolio
Management
© The McGraw−Hill
Companies, 2003
possibility. In general, there will be a significant number of nonzero ␣ values, some positive
and some negative.
Consider first how you would use the active portfolio once you found it. Suppose the
active portfolio (A) has been constructed and has the parameters

A
, ␤
A
, ␴
2
(e
A

)
The total variance of the active portfolio is the sum of its systematic variance, ␤
2
A

2
M
, plus the
nonsystematic variance, ␴
2
(e
A
). These three parameters, plus the mean and variance of the
index portfolio, are sufficient to identify the opportunity set generated by the active and pas-
sive portfolios.
Figure 20.11 shows the optimization process with active and passive portfolios. The dashed
efficient frontier line represents the universe of all securities, assuming they are all fairly
priced, that is, that all alphas are zero. By definition, the market index (M) is on this efficient
frontier and is tangent to the (dashed) capital market line (CML). In practice, our analysts do
not need to (indeed cannot) know this frontier, but they need to forecast the index portfolio
and construct the optimal risky portfolio using the index and active (A) portfolios. The opti-
mal portfolio (P) will lie on the capital allocation line (CAL) that lies above the CML.
From the viewpoint of an investor with superior analysis, the index portfolio will be in-
efficient; that is, the active portfolio (A) constructed from mispriced securities will lie above
the CML.
The optimal combination of the active portfolio with the passive portfolio takes off from
the construction of an optimal risky portfolio from two risky assets that we first encountered
in Chapter 6. As the active portfolio is not perfectly correlated with the index, further diversi-
fication—that is, mixing it with the index—is likely to be beneficial.
We can judge the success of active management, and the contribution of the active portfolio

(A), by the Sharpe measure (ratio of reward to variability) of the resultant risky portfolio (P),
compared with that of the index portfolio (M).
20 Performance Evaluation and Active Portfolio Management 711
active portfolio
In the context of the
Treynor-Black model,
the portfolio formed
by mixing analyzed
stocks with perceived
nonzero alpha values.
This portfolio is
ultimately mixed with
the passive market
index portfolio.
E(r)
E(r
A
)
A
P
M
σ
σ
A
CAL
CML
FIGURE 20.11
The optimization
process with active
and passive portfolios

Bodie−Kane−Marcus:
Essentials of Investments,
Fifth Edition
VI. Active Investment
Management
20. Performance Evaluation
and Active Portfolio
Management
© The McGraw−Hill
Companies, 2003
The mathematics of the efficient frontier reveal that the Sharpe measure of the risky port-
folio is
S(P) ϭ [S
2
(M) ϩ␣
2
A
/␴
2
(e
A
)]
1/2
(20.3)
Thus, the critical variable in determining the success of the active portfolio is its ratio of
alpha to nonsystematic risk, ␣
A
/␴(e
A
).

The intuition here is straightforward. You mix the active portfolio with the index for the
benefit of diversification. The position to take in the active portfolio relative to the market
portfolio depends on the ratio of the active portfolio’s abnormal return, ␣
A
, relative to its
weakness given by its diversifiable risk, ␴(e
A
). This ratio is sometimes referred to as the
appraisal ratio.
The contribution of individual securities (say, k) to the active portfolio (A) is analogous to
that of the active portfolio to the risky portfolio (P). It is measured by the appraisal ratio,

k
/␴(e
k
).
712 Part SIX Active Investment Management
SUMMARY
• The appropriate performance measure depends on the investment context. The Sharpe
measure is most appropriate when the portfolio represents the entire investment fund.
The Treynor measure or Jensen measure is appropriate when the portfolio is to be mixed
with several other assets, allowing for diversification of firm-specific risk outside of each
portfolio.
• The shifting mean and variance of actively managed portfolios make it harder to assess
performance. A typical example is the attempt of portfolio managers to time the market,
resulting in ever-changing portfolio betas and standard deviations.
• Common attribution procedures partition performance improvements to asset allocation,
sector selection, and security selection. Performance is assessed by calculating departures
of portfolio composition from a benchmark or neutral portfolio.
• Active portfolio managers attempt to construct a risky portfolio that improves on the

reward-to-variability (Sharpe) ratio of a passive strategy.
• Active management has two components: market timing (or, more generally, asset
allocation) and security analysis.
• The value of perfect market-timing ability is enormous. The rate of return to a perfect
market timer will be uncertain, but the risk cannot be measured by standard deviation,
because perfect timing dominates a passive strategy, providing only “good” surprises.
• Perfect-timing ability is equivalent to having a call option on the market portfolio. The
value of that option can be determined using valuation techniques such as the Black-
Scholes formula.
• The value of imperfect market timing depends on the sum of the probabilities of the true
outcome conditional on the forecast: P
1
ϩ P
2
Ϫ 1. If perfect timing is equivalent to call
option C, then imperfect timing can be valued by: (P
1
ϩ P
2
Ϫ 1)C.
• The Treynor-Black model is based on an index model that takes market-timing forecasts
as given. The investment manager uses security analysis to construct an active portfolio.
The active portfolio is mixed with the index portfolio to maximize the Sharpe measure
of the optimal risky portfolio.
• In the Treynor-Black model, the weight of each analyzed security is proportional to
the ratio of its alpha to its residual variance.
www.mhhe.com/bkm
Bodie−Kane−Marcus:
Essentials of Investments,
Fifth Edition

VI. Active Investment
Management
20. Performance Evaluation
and Active Portfolio
Management
© The McGraw−Hill
Companies, 2003
20 Performance Evaluation and Active Portfolio Management 713
www.mhhe.com/bkm
KEY
TERMS
active portfolio, 711
bogey, 694
comparison universe, 684
Jensen measure, 686
market timing, 702
Sharpe measure, 686
Treynor-Black model, 710
Treynor measure, 686
PROBLEM
SETS
Questions 1–3 appeared in past CFA examinations.
1. A plan sponsor with a portfolio manager who invests in small-capitalization, high-growth
stocks should have the plan sponsor’s performance measured against which one of the
following?
a. S&P 500 index.
b. Wilshire 5000 index.
c. Dow Jones Industrial Average.
d. Russell 2000 index.
2. Assume you purchased a rental property for $50,000 and sold it one year later for

$55,000 (there was no mortgage on the property). At the time of the sale, you paid $2,000
in commissions and $600 in taxes. If you received $6,000 in rental income (all of it
received at the end of the year), what annual rate of return did you earn?
a. 15.3%
b. 15.9%
c. 16.8%
d. 17.1%
3. A two-year investment of $2,000 results in a return of $150 at the end of the first year
and a return of $150 at the end of the second year, in addition to the return of the original
investment. The internal rate of return on the investment is:
a. 6.4%
b. 7.5%
c. 15.0%
d. None of the above
4. Based on current dividend yields and expected capital gains, the expected rates of return
on portfolios A and B are 11% and 14%, respectively. The beta of A is 0.8 while that of B
is 1.5. The T-bill rate is currently 6%, while the expected rate of return of the S&P 500
index is 12%. The standard deviation of portfolio A is 10% annually, while that of B is
31%, and that of the index is 20%.
a. If you currently hold a market index portfolio, would you choose to add either of these
portfolios to your holdings? Explain.
b. If instead you could invest only in bills and one of these portfolios, which would you
choose?
5. Evaluate the timing and selection abilities of four managers whose performances are
plotted in the following four scatter diagrams.
Bodie−Kane−Marcus:
Essentials of Investments,
Fifth Edition
VI. Active Investment
Management

20. Performance Evaluation
and Active Portfolio
Management
© The McGraw−Hill
Companies, 2003
714 Part SIX Active Investment Management
www.mhhe.com/bkm
6. Consider the following information regarding the performance of a money manager
in a recent month. The table presents the actual return of each sector of the manager’s
portfolio in column (1), the fraction of the portfolio allocated to each sector in
column (2), the benchmark or neutral sector allocations in column (3), and
the returns of sector indexes in column (4).
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Actual Actual Benchmark Index
Return Weight Weight Return
Equity 2.0% 0.70 0.60 2.5% (S&P 500)
Bonds 1.0 0.20 0.30 1.2 (Aggregate Bond index)
Cash 0.5 0.10 0.10 0.5
a. What was the manager’s return in the month? What was her over- or
underperformance?
b. What was the contribution of security selection to relative performance?
c. What was the contribution of asset allocation to relative performance? Confirm that
the sum of selection and allocation contributions equals her total “excess” return
relative to the bogey.
7. Conventional wisdom says one should measure a manager’s investment performance
over an entire market cycle. What arguments support this contention? What arguments
contradict it?
8. Does the use of universes of managers with similar investment styles to evaluate relative
investment performance overcome the statistical problems associated with instability of
beta or total variability?

9. During a particular year, the T-bill rate was 6%, the market return was 14%, and a
portfolio manager with beta of 0.5 realized a return of 10%. Evaluate the manager based
on the portfolio alpha.
C
r
P
– r
f
r
M
– r
f
A
r
P
– r
f
r
M
– r
f
D
r
P
– r
f
r
M
– r
f

B
r
P
– r
f
r
M
– r
f
Bodie−Kane−Marcus:
Essentials of Investments,
Fifth Edition
VI. Active Investment
Management
20. Performance Evaluation
and Active Portfolio
Management
© The McGraw−Hill
Companies, 2003
10. The chairman provides you with the following data, covering one year, concerning the
portfolios of two of the fund’s equity managers (manager A and manager B). Although
the portfolios consist primarily of common stocks, cash reserves are included in the
calculation of both portfolio betas and performance. By way of perspective, selected
data for the financial markets are included in the following table.
Total Return Beta
Manager A 24.0% 1.0
Manager B 30.0 1.5
S&P 500 21.0
Lehman Bond Index 31.0
91-day Treasury bills 12.0

a. Calculate and compare the risk-adjusted performance of the two managers relative to
each other and to the S&P 500.
b. Explain two reasons the conclusions drawn from this calculation may be misleading.
11. Carl Karl, a portfolio manager for the Alpine Trust Company, has been responsible since
1990 for the City of Alpine’s Employee Retirement Plan, a municipal pension fund.
Alpine is a growing community, and city services and employee payrolls have expanded
in each of the past 10 years. Contributions to the plan in fiscal 1995 exceeded benefit
payments by a three-to-one ratio.
The plan’s Board of Trustees directed Karl five years ago to invest for total return
over the long term. However, as trustees of this highly visible public fund, they
cautioned him that volatile or erratic results could cause them embarrassment. They also
noted a state statute that mandated that not more than 25% of the plan’s assets (at cost)
be invested in common stocks.
At the annual meeting of the trustees in November 1995, Karl presented the
following portfolio and performance report to the Board.
ALPINE EMPLOYEE RETIREMENT PLAN
At Cost At Market
Asset Mix as of 9/30/95 (millions) (millions)
Fixed-income assets:
Short-term securities $ 4.5 11.0% $ 4.5 11.4%
Long-term bonds and mortgages 26.5 64.7 23.5 59.5
Common stocks 10.0 24.3 11.5 29.1
$41.0 100.0% $39.5 100.0%
INVESTMENT PERFORMANCE
Annual Rates of
Return for Periods
Ending 9/30/95
5 Years 1 Year
Total Alpine Fund:
Time-weighted 8.2% 5.2%

Dollar-weighted (Internal) 7.7% 4.8%
Assumed actuarial return 6.0% 6.0%
20 Performance Evaluation and Active Portfolio Management 715
www.mhhe.com/bkm
Bodie−Kane−Marcus:
Essentials of Investments,
Fifth Edition
VI. Active Investment
Management
20. Performance Evaluation
and Active Portfolio
Management
© The McGraw−Hill
Companies, 2003
U.S. Treasury bills 7.5% 11.3%
Large sample of pension funds
(average 60% equities, 40% fixed income) 10.1% 14.3%
Common stocks—Alpine Fund 13.3% 14.3%
Average portfolio beta coefficient 0.90 0.89
Standard & Poor’s 500 stock index 13.8% 21.1%
Fixed-income securities—Alpine Fund 6.7% 1.0%
Salomon Brothers’ bond index 4.0% Ϫ11.4%
Karl was proud of his performance and was chagrined when a trustee made the
following critical observations:
a. “Our one-year results were terrible, and it’s what you’ve done for us lately that
counts most.”
b. “Our total fund performance was clearly inferior compared to the large sample of
other pension funds for the last five years. What else could this reflect except poor
management judgment?”
c. “Our common stock performance was especially poor for the five-year period.”

d. “Why bother to compare your returns to the return from Treasury bills and the
actuarial assumption rate? What your competition could have earned for us or how
we would have fared if invested in a passive index (which doesn’t charge a fee) are
the only relevant measures of performance.”
e. “Who cares about time-weighted return? If it can’t pay pensions, what good is it!”
Appraise the merits of each of these statements and give counterarguments that Mr. Karl
can use.
12. Historical data suggest the standard deviation of an all-equity strategy is about 5.5% per
month. Suppose the risk-free rate is now 1% per month and market volatility is at its
historical level. What would be a fair monthly fee to a perfect market timer, according
to the Black-Scholes formula?
13. A fund manager scrutinizing the record of two market timers comes up with this
information:
Number of months that r
M
Ͼ r
f
135
Correctly predicted by timer A 78
Correctly predicted by timer B 86
Number of months that r
M
Ͻ r
f
92
Correctly predicted by timer A 57
Correctly predicted by timer B 50
a. What are the conditional probabilities, P
1
and P

2
, and the total ability parameters for
timers A and B?
b. Using the historical data of problem 12, what is a fair monthly fee for the two
timers?
14. A portfolio manager summarizes the input from the macro and micro forecasts in the
following table:
716 Part SIX Active Investment Management
www.mhhe.com/bkm
Bodie−Kane−Marcus:
Essentials of Investments,
Fifth Edition
VI. Active Investment
Management
20. Performance Evaluation
and Active Portfolio
Management
© The McGraw−Hill
Companies, 2003
Micro Forecasts
Residual Standard
Asset Expected Return (%) Beta Deviation (%)
Stock A 20 1.3 58
Stock B 18 1.8 71
Stock C 17 0.7 60
Stock D 12 1.0 55
Macro Forecasts
Asset Expected Return (%) Standard Deviation (%)
T-bills 8 0
Passive equity portfolio 16 23

a. Calculate expected excess returns, alpha values, and residual variances for these
stocks.
b. Construct the optimal risky portfolio.
c. What is Sharpe’s measure for the optimal portfolio and how much of it is contributed
by the active portfolio? What is the M
2
?
20 Performance Evaluation and Active Portfolio Management 717
www.mhhe.com/bkm
WEBMASTER
Analyzing Performance
Go to http://www
.morningstar.com/Cover/Funds.html to access the Morningstar Fund
Quick Rank program.
Using this screening program, get a listing of funds that are ranked the highest in
both 5- and 10-year returns. From those lists, select the highest-ranking fund that ap-
pears on both lists. Once you have identified the fund, click on its ticker to get a Morn-
ingstar Quicktake report. Using that report, answer the following questions:
1. What is the fund’s Sharpe ratio?
2. What are the beta and alpha coefficients for both the S&P 500 and the Russell
2000 Index?
3. What are the top three investment sectors in the fund?
SOLUTIONS TO
1. Sharpe: (¯r Ϫ ¯r
f
)/␴
S
P
ϭ (35 Ϫ 6)/42 ϭ 0.69
S

M
ϭ (28 Ϫ 6)/30 ϭ 0.733
Jensen: ¯r Ϫ [¯r
f
ϩ␤(¯r
M
Ϫ ¯r
f
)]

P
ϭ 35 Ϫ [6 ϩ 1.2(28 Ϫ 6)] ϭ 2.6%

M
ϭ 0
Treynor: (¯r Ϫ ¯r
f
)/␤
T
P
ϭ (35 Ϫ 6)/1.2 ϭ 24.2
T
M
ϭ (28 Ϫ 6)/1.0 ϭ 22
Concept
CHECKS
<
Bodie−Kane−Marcus:
Essentials of Investments,
Fifth Edition

VI. Active Investment
Management
20. Performance Evaluation
and Active Portfolio
Management
© The McGraw−Hill
Companies, 2003
718 Part SIX Active Investment Management
www.mhhe.com/bkm
2. Performance attribution
First compute the new bogey performance as
(0.70 ϫ 5.81) ϩ (0.25 ϫ 1.45) ϩ (0.05 ϫ 0.48) ϭ 4.45%
a. Contribution of asset allocation to performance
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) ؍ (3) ؋ (4)
Actual Benchmark Index Contribution to
Weight Weight Excess Return Performance
Market in Market in Market Weight (%) (%)
Equity 0.70 0.70 0.00 5.81 0.000
Fixed-income 0.07 0.25 Ϫ0.18 1.45 Ϫ.261
Cash 0.23 0.05 0.18 0.48 .086
Contribution of asset allocation Ϫ.175
b. Contribution of selection to total performance
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) ؍ (3) ؋ (4)
Portfolio Index Excess
Performance Performance Performance Portfolio Contribution
Market (%) (%) (%) Weight (%)
Equity 7.28 5.00 2.28 0.70 1.60
Fixed-income 1.89 1.45 0.44 0.07 0.03
Contribution of selection within markets 1.63
3. Beginning-of-period fund: F

0
ϭ $1
End-of-period fund for each strategy:
16.98 Strategy ϭ Bills only
F
1
ϭ
c
1,987.01 Strategy ϭ Market only
115,233.89 Strategy ϭ Perfect timing
Number of periods: N ϭ 76 years
Annual compounded rate:
(1 ϩ r
A
)
N
ϭ
r
A
ϭ ¢≤
1/N
Ϫ 1
3.80% Strategy ϭ Bills only
r
A
ϭ
c
10.51% Strategy ϭ Market only
16.57% Strategy ϭ Perfect timing
4. The timer will guess bear or bull markets randomly. One-half of all bull markets will be preceded

by a correct forecast, and similarly, one-half of all bear markets will be preceded by a correct
forecast. Hence, P
1
ϩ P
2
Ϫ 1 ϭ 1/2 ϩ 1/2 Ϫ 1 ϭ 0.
F
1
F
0
F
1
F
0
Bodie−Kane−Marcus:
Essentials of Investments,
Fifth Edition
VI. Active Investment
Management
21. International Investing
© The McGraw−Hill
Companies, 2003
21
720
AFTER STUDYING THIS CHAPTER
YOU SHOULD BE ABLE TO:
Demonstrate the advantages of international diversification.
Formulate hedge strategies to offset the currency risk
involved in international investments.
Understand international investment strategies.

Decompose investment returns into contributing factors
such as country, currency, and stock selection.
INTERNATIONAL
INVESTING
>
>
>
>
Bodie−Kane−Marcus:
Essentials of Investments,
Fifth Edition
VI. Active Investment
Management
21. International Investing
© The McGraw−Hill
Companies, 2003
Related Websites

This site includes information on American Depository
Receipts.

The site above has information on all aspects of
international investing.

This site gives information on international closed-end
investment funds.

This site provides information on international, regional,
and country funds.


This site provides information on international
economics and performance in regions.

This site offers information on international index
securities that can be used to secure portfolio
diversification.
A
lthough we in the United States customarily treat the S&P 500 as the market
index portfolio, this practice is increasingly inappropriate. Equities represent
less than 25% of total U.S. wealth and a much smaller proportion than that of
world wealth. In this chapter, we look beyond domestic markets to survey issues of ex-
tended diversification.
In one sense, international investing may be viewed as no more than a straight-
forward generalization of our earlier treatment of portfolio selection with a larger
menu of assets from which to construct a portfolio. One faces similar issues of diver-
sification, security analysis, security selection, and asset allocation. On the other
hand, international investments pose some problems not encountered in domestic
markets. Among these are the presence of exchange rate risk, restrictions on capital
flows across national boundaries, an added dimension of political risk and country-
specific regulations, and differing accounting practices in different countries.
We begin by looking at market capitalization of stock exchanges around the
world and its relation to the home country GDP. Next, we examine exchange rate risk
and how such risk can be mitigated by using foreign exchange futures and forward
contracts. We also introduce political and country-specific risk that must be consid-
ered in the overall risk assessment of international investments. We then examine cor-
relation across country portfolios with and without hedging foreign exchange risk.
Based on these insights, we assess the efficacy of investing globally in the context of
equilibrium in international capital markets. Finally, we show how performance attri-
bution procedures can be adapted to an international setting.
Bodie−Kane−Marcus:

Essentials of Investments,
Fifth Edition
VI. Active Investment
Management
21. International Investing
© The McGraw−Hill
Companies, 2003
21.1 GLOBAL MARKETS FOR EQUITIES
Developed Countries
To appreciate the myopia of an exclusive investment focus on U.S. stocks and bonds, consider
the data in Table 21.1. Developed (high-income) countries are defined as those with per capita
income exceeding $9,300 (in 2000), and their broad stock indexes are generally less risky than
those of emerging markets. The World Bank listed 52 developed countries in 2000, many of
them with very small exchanges. Our list includes 25 countries with the largest equity capi-
talization, the smallest of which is New Zealand with a capitalization of $19 billion in 2001.
These countries made up 79% of the World gross domestic product in 2001.
The first five columns of Table 21.1 show market capitalization over the years 1996–2001.
The first line shows capitalization for all world exchanges, showing total capitalization of cor-
porate equity in 2001 as $25.7 trillion, of which U.S. stock exchanges made up $13.2 trillion
(49%). The figures in these columns demonstrate the volatility of these markets; indeed, world
capitalization in 2001 was less than it was two years earlier and in the entire Pacific Basin it
was less than it was in 1996!
The next three columns of Table 21.1 show country equity capitalization as a percentage of
the world’s in 2001 and 1996 and the growth in capitalization over the five years 1996–2001.
The large volatility of country stock indexes resulted in significant changes in relative size. For
example, U.S. weight in the world equity portfolio increased from 37% in 1996 to 49% in 2001,
while that of Japan decreased from 24% to 11%. The weights of the five largest countries
behind the U.S. (Japan, U.K., France, Germany, and Switzerland) added up to 39.2% in 2001,
so that in the universe of these six countries alone, the weight of the U.S. was only 62%
[49/(49 ϩ 39.2)]. Clearly, U.S. stocks may not comprise an adequately diversified portfolio

of equities.
Unlike the 1980s and early 1990s, the period 1996–2001 saw a decline in the value of equi-
ties of the Pacific Basin (growth of Ϫ4%), but a resurgence in North America (growth of
136%) and Europe (104%). These numbers show that economic position of countries is just as
precarious as the stock prices that capitalize the future value of the particular corporate sectors
of these economies.
The last tree columns of Table 21.1 show GDP, per capita GDP, and the equity capitaliza-
tion as a percentage of GDP for the year 2001. As we would expect, per capital GDP in de-
veloped countries is not as variable across countries as total GDP, which is determined in part
by total population. But market capitalization as a percentage of GDP is quite variable, sug-
gesting widespread differences in economic structure even across developed countries. We re-
turn to this issue in the next section.
Emerging Markets
For a passive strategy one could argue that a portfolio of equities of just the six countries with
the largest capitalization would make up 79.2% (in 2001) of the world portfolio and may be
sufficiently diversified. This argument will not hold for active portfolios that seek to tilt in-
vestments toward promising assets. Active portfolios will naturally include many stocks or
even indexes of emerging markets.
Table 21.2 makes the point. Surely, active portfolio managers must prudently scour stocks
in markets such as China, Brazil, or Korea. Table 21.2 shows data from the 20 largest emerg-
ing markets, the most notable of which is China with equity capitalization of $170 billion
(0.66% of world capitalization) in 2001, and growth of 651% over the five years 1966–2001.
But managers also would not want to have missed a market like Poland (0.09% of world capi-
talization) with a growth of 287% over the same years.
722 Part SIX Active Investment Management
Bodie−Kane−Marcus:
Essentials of Investments,
Fifth Edition
VI. Active Investment
Management

21. International Investing
© The McGraw−Hill
Companies, 2003
723
TABLE 21.1
Market capitalization of stock exchanges in developed countries
Capitalization
GDP per as % of
U.S. Dollars (billions) Percent of World Growth GDP Capita GDP
2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 2001 1996 1996–2001 2001 2001 2001
World $25,711 $31,668 $26,198 $20,703 $17,966 $14,494 100% 100% 77% 30,960 5,450 83
North America 13,169 15,601 13,166 10,008 7,685 5,590 51.2 38.6 135.6
United States 12,597 14,882 12,623 9,528 7,271 5,294 49.0 36.5 137.9 10,208 35,900 123
Canada 572 719 543 479 413 295 2.2 2.0 94.0 700 22,525 82
Europe 7,305 9,185 7,657 6,948 4,878 3,585 28 25 104
United Kingdom 2,256 2,639 2,475 2,179 1,635 1,206 8.8 8.3 87 1,424 23,750 158
France 1,119 1,356 937 843 518 427 4.4 2.9 162 1,307 21,910 86
Germany 896 1,204 1,062 992 709 481 3.5 3.3 86 1,848 22,500 48
Switzerland 633 712 662 596 447 303 2.5 2.1 109 247 34,019 256
Netherlands 559 723 634 607 479 339 2.2 2.3 65 381 23,810 147
Italy 556 736 526 464 247 214 2.2 1.5 160 1,090 18,950 51
Spain 336 337 310 311 212 150 1.3 1.0 124 582 14,590 58
Sweden 212 375 253 247 188 139 0.8 1.0 52 210 23,580 101
Finland 164 379 173 93 60 42 0.6 0.3 295 121 23,260 136
Belgium 130 158 152 173 105 82 0.5 0.6 58 230 22,420 56
Denmark 90 101 75 88 61 44 0.3 0.3 103 163 30,450 55
Ireland 76 75 58 59 36 27 0.3 0.2 185 103 27,140 73
Norway 69 54 52 56 47 35 0.3 0.2 100 165 36,600 42
Greece 55 88 83 51 27 17 0.2 0.1 224 116 11,000 47
Portugal 49 74 59 75 47 23 0.2 0.2 111 110 10,940 45

Israel 39 47 35 29 24 18 0.2 0.1 120 110 17,159 35
Austria 24 28 31 35 27 26 0.1 02 Ϫ8 189 23,078 13
New Zealand 19 23 26 26 36 29 0.1 0.2 Ϫ34 49 12,763 39
Pacific Basin 4,642 6,184 4,764 3,201 4,729 4,830 18 33 Ϫ4
Japan 2,947 4,246 3,092 2,188 3,138 3,509 11 24 Ϫ16 4,148 32,720 71
Hong Kong 532 553 404 254 452 289 2.1 2.0 84 162 10,940 329
Australia 363 384 378 249 276 219 1.4 1.5 65 357 18,459 102
Taiwan 205 331 260 173 232 152 0.8 1.0 35 282 12,620 73
Singapore 113 143 133 72 116 138 0.4 0.9 Ϫ18 86 20,880 132
Source: Datastream, July 2002.
Market Capitalization
Bodie−Kane−Marcus:
Essentials of Investments,
Fifth Edition
VI. Active Investment
Management
21. International Investing
© The McGraw−Hill
Companies, 2003
724
TABLE 21.2
Market capitalization of stock exchanges in emerging markets
Capitalization
GDP per as % of
U.S. Dollars (billions) Percent of World Growth GDP Capita GDP
2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 2001 1996 1996–2001 2001 2001 2001
China $170 $ 94 $ 78 $ 67 $ 48 $ 23 0.66% 0.16% 651% 1,180 928 14%
Brazil 169 220 155 135 175 86 0.66 0.59 97 503 2,810 34
Korea 151 218 181 35 95 104 0.59 0.72 45 423 8,870 36
Mexico 140 128 115 96 97 74 0.55 0.51 89 621 6,190 23

South Africa 101 123 126 121 148 124 0.39 0.86 Ϫ19 112 2,520 90
India 88 139 93 72 113 88 0.34 0.61 Ϫ1 485 470 18
Malaysia 76 98 90 50 170 167 0.30 1.15 Ϫ54 89 3,720 86
Russia 66 49 35 44 93 37 0.26 0.25 80 310 2,144 21
Chile 53 49 47 45 61 48 0.20 0.33 10 64 4,170 82
Turkey 36 75 39 54 36 24 0.14 0.16 50 148 2,230 24
Argentina 29 37 51 48 56 43 0.11 0.30 Ϫ31 267 7,120 11
Thailand 26 30 46 17 46 89 0.10 0.61 Ϫ71 115 1,820 23
Poland 22 29 25 14 7 6 0.09 0.04 287 176 4,566 13
Philippines 20 23 41 26 55 62 0.08 0.42 Ϫ68 71 862 28
Indonesia 19 32 39 12 76 60 0.07 0.41 Ϫ68 145 688 13
Czech Republic 10 13 12 13 11 13 0.04 0.09 Ϫ26 52 5,137 19
Hungary 9 14 14 15 8 4 0.04 0.03 128 56 5,482 16
Peru 6 8 7 8 11 10 0.02 0.07 Ϫ36 54 2,070 11
Colombia 6 5 7 10 22 17 0.02 0.12 Ϫ65 83 1,940 7
Venezuela 4 4 4 4 10 4 0.02 0.03 2 130 5,280 3
Source: Datastream, July 2002.
Market Capitalization
Bodie−Kane−Marcus:
Essentials of Investments,
Fifth Edition
VI. Active Investment
Management
21. International Investing
© The McGraw−Hill
Companies, 2003
These 20 emerging markets make up 16% of the world GDP and, together with the 25 de-
veloped markets in Table 21.1, make up 95% of the world GDP. Per capita GDP in these coun-
tries in 2001 was quite variable, ranging from $470 (India) to $8,870 (Korea); still, no active
manager would want to ignore India in an international portfolio. Market capitalization as a

percent of GDP, which ranges from 3% (Venezuela) to 90% (South Africa), suggests that these
markets are expected to show significant growth over the coming years, even absent spectac-
ular growth in GDP.
The growth of capitalization in emerging markets over 1966–2001 was much more volatile
than growth in developed countries (as disastrous as Ϫ71% for Thailand), suggesting that both
risk and rewards in this segment of the globe may be substantial.
Market Capitalization and GDP
The contemporary view of economic development (rigorously stated in deSoto 2000) holds
that a major requirement for economic advancement is a developed code of business laws, in-
stitutions, and regulation that allows citizens to legally own, capitalize, and trade capital as-
sets. As a corollary, we expect that development of equity markets will serve as catalysts for
enrichment of the population, that is, that countries with larger relative capitalization of equi-
ties will tend to be richer.
Figure 21.1 is a simple (perhaps simplistic since other relevant explanatory variables are
omitted) rendition of the argument that a developed market for corporate equity contributes
to the enrichment of the population. The R-square of the regression line shown in Figure
21.1 is 35% and the regression coefficient is .73, suggesting that an increase of 1% in the
ratio of market capitalization to GDP is associated with an increase in per capita GDP of
0.73%. It is remarkable that not one of the 25 developed countries is below the regression
line; only low-income emerging markets lie below the line. Countries like Venezuela and
Norway that lie above the line, that is, exhibit higher per capita GDP than predicted by the
regression, enjoy oil wealth that contributes to population income. Countries below the line,
such as Indonesia, South Africa, Philippines, and India, suffered from deterioration of
the business environment due to political strife and/or government policies that restricted
21 International Investing 725
FIGURE 21.1
Per capita GDP tends
to be higher when
market capitalization
as a percentage of

GDP is higher.
(log scale)
100000
10000
1000
100
1 10 100 1,000
Venezuela
Argentina
Austria
Norway
U.S.
South Africa
Philippines
India
Market capitalization as a percentage of GDP
Indonesia
China
Per capita GDP ($)
Developed countries Emerging markets Regression line
Bodie−Kane−Marcus:
Essentials of Investments,
Fifth Edition
VI. Active Investment
Management
21. International Investing
© The McGraw−Hill
Companies, 2003
the private sector. China’s policies of freeing up economic activities contributed to the re-
markable growth in market capitalization over 1996–2001. The expected continuation of

this process will likely move China toward the predicted relationship in coming years.
Home-Country Bias
One would expect that most investors, particularly institutional and professional investors,
would be aware of the opportunities offered by international investing. Yet in practice, in-
vestor portfolios notoriously overweight home-country stocks compared to a neutral indexing
strategy and underweight, or even completely ignore, foreign equities. This has come to be
known as the home-country bias. Despite a continuous increase in cross-border investing,
home-country bias still dominates investor portfolios.
21.2 RISK FACTORS IN INTERNATIONAL INVESTING
Opportunities in international investments do not come free of risk or of the cost of special-
ized analysis. The risk factors that are unique to international investments are exchange rate
risk and country-specific risk, discussed in the next two sections.
Exchange Rate Risk
It is best to begin with a simple example.
We can generalize from Example 21.1. The $20,000 is exchanged for $20,000/E
0
pounds,
where E
0
denotes the original exchange rate ($2/£). The U.K. investment grows to
(20,000/E
0
)[1 ϩ r
f
(UK)] British pounds, where r
f
(UK) is the risk-free rate in the United King-
dom. The pound proceeds ultimately are converted back to dollars at the subsequent exchange
rate E
1

, for total dollar proceeds of 20,000(E
1
/E
0
)[1 ϩ r
f
(UK)]. The dollar-denominated return
on the investment in British bills, therefore, is
1 ϩ r (US) ϭ [1 ϩ r
f
(UK)]E
1
/E
0
(21.1)
We see in Equation 21.1 that the dollar-denominated return for a U.S. investor equals the
pound-denominated return times the exchange rate “return.” For a U.S. investor, the invest-
ment in British bills is a combination of a safe investment in the United Kingdom and a risky
investment in the performance of the pound relative to the dollar. Here, the pound fared
poorly, falling from a value of $2.00 to only $1.80. The loss on the pound more than offsets
the earnings on the British bill.
726 Part SIX Active Investment Management
21.1 EXAMPLE
Exchange
Rate Risk
Consider an investment in risk-free British government bills paying 10% annual interest in
British pounds. While these U.K. bills would be the risk-free asset to a British investor, this is
not the case for a U.S. investor. Suppose, for example, the current exchange rate is $2 per
pound, and the U.S. investor starts with $20,000. That amount can be exchanged for
£10,000 and invested at a riskless 10% rate in the United Kingdom to provide £11,000 in

one year.
What happens if the dollar–pound exchange rate varies over the year? Say that during the
year, the pound depreciates relative to the dollar, so that by year-end only $1.80 is required
to purchase £1. The £11,000 can be exchanged at the year-end exchange rate for only
$19,800 (ϭ £11,000 ϫ $1.80/£), resulting in a loss of $200 relative to the initial $20,000
investment. Despite the positive 10% pound-denominated return, the dollar-denominated re-
turn is a negative 1%.

×