Tải bản đầy đủ (.pdf) (252 trang)

Strategic innovation in russia towards a sustainable and profitable national innovation system

Bạn đang xem bản rút gọn của tài liệu. Xem và tải ngay bản đầy đủ của tài liệu tại đây (5.09 MB, 252 trang )


Taco C. R. van Someren and Shuhua van Someren-Wang

Strategic Innovation in Russia
Towards a Sustainable and Profitable National Innovation System


Taco C. R. van Someren
Ynnovate, Hilversum, The Netherlands
Shuhua van Someren-Wang
Ynnovate, Hilversum, The Netherlands

ISBN 978-3-319-41080-7 e-ISBN 978-3-319-41081-4
DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-41081-4
Library of Congress Control Number: 2016950914
© Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2017
This Springer imprint is published by Springer Nature
This work is subject to copyright. All rights are reserved by the Publisher, whether the whole or part
of the material is concerned, specifically the rights of translation, reprinting, reuse of illustrations,
recitation, broadcasting, reproduction on microfilms or in any other physical way, and transmission
or information storage and retrieval, electronic adaptation, computer software, or by similar or
dissimilar methodology now known or hereafter developed.
The use of general descriptive names, registered names, trademarks, service marks, etc. in this
publication does not imply, even in the absence of a specific statement, that such names are exempt
from the relevant protective laws and regulations and therefore free for general use.
The publisher, the authors and the editors are safe to assume that the advice and information in this
book are believed to be true and accurate at the date of publication. Neither the publisher nor the
authors or the editors give a warranty, express or implied, with respect to the material contained
herein or for any errors or omissions that may have been made.
Printed on acid-free paper
The registered company is Springer International Publishing AG Switzerland




Contents
1 The Challenge:​ Renewal of the Russian Innovation System
1.​1 Strategic Innovation Replaces Technology
1.​2 The Relevance of Strategic Innovation for Russia
1.​2.​1 Not Diversification but Renewal of Domestic Industries Is Key
1.​2.​2 Future World Society
1.​2.​3 Sustainability
1.​2.​4 Geopolitical Power Shifts
1.​2.​5 Market Economy quo vadis?​!
1.​3 Russian Heroic but Unknown Innovation History
1.​4 Current Status of Innovation in the Russian Economy
1.​4.​1 Insufficient Innovation Performance
1.​4.​2 Insufficient Internationaliza​tion
1.​4.​3 Insufficient Entrepreneurial Activity
1.​4.​4 Insufficient Contribution of SMEs
1.​5 National Innovation System
1.​6 Milestones of Innovation
1.​7 The Strategy
1.​8 Bottlenecks
1.​9 Megatrends
1.​10 Russia Aims at the Technology Frontier
1.​11 Overview of This Book
Literature


2 The Solution:​ Strategic Innovation Money Maker Model Versus Technology Frontier Money
Taker Model
2.​1 The Need for a New Big Picture

2.​1.​1 Macro level and Massive Outlook
2.​1.​2 Meso level and Major Renewal
2.​1.​3 Micro level and Mega Impact
2.​2 Major Developments Requiring Strategic Innovation
2.​2.​1 Sustainable Economy
2.​2.​2 Internet of Things and Industry 5.​0
2.​2.​3 New Dominant Regions
2.​2.​4 World Economy Replaces Globalization
2.​2.​5 Big Unknown
2.​2.​6 Common Denominator of Sustainability, Internet of Things, New Dominant
Regions, World Economy and Big Unknown
2.​3 Consequences for Russia
2.​4 Growth Cycle Versus Technology Frontier:​ Money Maker Versus Money Taker
2.​5 Russia ’ s Position on the Growth Cycle
Literature
3 The Instrument:​ Strategic Innovation as a New Foundation for Russian Innovation System
3.​1 The Mind Shift from Technology to Future Earning Power Needs New Theory
3.​1.​1 Strategy Concepts Cannot Explain “What Happens Here?​”
3.​1.​2 Innovation Theories Cannot Explain “What Happens Here?​”
3.​1.​3 Strategy and Innovation Concepts Compared
3.​2 From Parrot-Economy to 24-Karat:​ From Technology Frontier Towards Strategic
Innovation


3.​3 The Innovation Matryoshka
3.​4 The Six Pillars of Strategic Innovation Theory
3.​5 Entrepreneurial Function
3.​6 Growth Cycle Is More Than Disruption
3.​7 Non-technical Innovations
3.​7.​1 Scope of Non-technical Innovation

3.​7.​2 Impact of Non-technological Innovation
3.​7.​3 Non-technological Innovations Are Hard to Imitate
3.​7.​4 Implicit and Tacit Innovation
3.​8 Ultimate Power of Time
3.​8.​1 Time Is the Master of the Universe
3.​8.​2 The Basic but Unnoticed Role of Time
3.​8.​3 Tacit Knowledge Does not Exist, It Is the Time Factor
3.​8.​4 The Seven Time Dimensions
3.​8.​5 Time Culture:​ A Profound Hidden Force of Societal Development and Progress
3.​8.​6 Time Arrow:​ Future or Backwards Oriented Society
3.​8.​7 Time Control:​ Who Controls Time Owns Power
3.​8.​8 Timing:​ Multiplier of Profits and Losses
3.​8.​9 Time Duration:​ Creator and Destroyer of Wealth
3.​8.​10 Time Consumption:​ From Ubiquity to Scarcity
3.​8.​11 Time Intensity:​ Evolutionary, Revolutionary, Speedy and Risky Times
3.​8.​12 Wrap Up Seven Time Dimensions
3.​8.​13 Dynamic Production Function
3.​9 Dynamic Value


3.​9.​1 From Profit to Dynamic Value
3.​9.​2 Multiplier Time Effect and Exponential Growth
3.​9.​3 Dynamic Value as Modus Operandi of Strategic Innovation
3.​9.​4 Relevance of Dynamic Value for Russia
3.​10 Emulation as Endless Race of Outperforming and not of Disruption
3.​10.​1 Emulation Is Core of Progress and Prosperity
3.​10.​2 The 4I Emulation Scheme for Russia needs Tailor Made Approach
3.​11 Strategic Innovation Theory Elevates Russia in World Innovation League
Literature
4 The Management:​ Unleashing the Strategic Innovation Potential

4.​1 Growth Cycle and Strategic Innovation
4.​2 Growth Cycle Phases
4.​2.​1 Pre-seed and Seed:​ Lead or Bleed
4.​2.​2 Start-up Smart
4.​2.​3 Scale or Fail
4.​2.​4 Incumbents Defend or Expand
4.​2.​5 From Renewal to Future Crown Jewel
4.​3 Myth Busting the New Economy
4.​3.​1 Myth 1:​ Technology
4.​3.​2 Myth 2:​ Knowledge Economy
4.​3.​3 Myth 3:​ Disruption
4.​3.​4 Myth 4:​ Open Innovation
4.​3.​5 Myth 5:​ Cooperation
4.​3.​6 Myth 6:​ Network Firms


4.​3.​7 Myth 7:​ Sharing Economy
4.​3.​8 Myth 8:​ Tacit Knowledge
4.​3.​9 Myth 9:​ Costless Information
4.​3.​10 Myth 10:​ Obsolete Production Function
4.​4 Back to Basics for Russian Innovation System
4.​5 The Management Basics of Strategic Innovation
4.​6 Future Earnings:​ Creating Company of the Future
4.​7 Growth Phase Management
4.​7.​1 Aspire
4.​7.​2 Discover
4.​7.​3 Create
4.​7.​4 Select
4.​7.​5 Institutionalize​
4.​7.​6 Expand

4.​7.​7 Exploit
4.​7.​8 Dominate
4.​7.​9 Reset
4.​7.​10 Emerge
4.​8 Longitudinal Management
4.​8.​1 Strategic Innovation Leadership
4.​8.​2 Institutional Innovation
4.​8.​3 Corporate Governance
4.​8.​4 Business Development
4.​8.​5 Business Model Formulation and Execution


4.​8.​6 Industrial Governance as Power
4.​8.​7 Cross Cultural Management
4.​8.​8 Dynamic Value
4.​9 Russian Volga Amur Model for Industrial Leadership
Literature
5 The Internationaliza​tion:​ Russian Cross-cultural Strategic Innovations
5.​1 Why Does Russia Have to Integrate Strategic Innovations Across the Border?​
5.​1.​1 From Creativity to Russian Strategic Innovations
5.​1.​2 From Culture Diversity to Russian Strategic Innovation Context
5.​1.​3 From Trade Partners to Triple E of Russian Strategic Innovations
5.​2 From Lose-Lose to Win-Win, How Can Russia and China Cooperate in International
Strategic Innovations?​
5.​2.​1 The Lose-Lose History of Sino-Russia Relationship
5.​2.​2 The New Strategic Innovation Chances for China and Russia Looking for Win-Win
5.​2.​3 Huawei as an Example of the Chinese Strategic Innovations in Russia
5.​2.​4 How Should Russia Work with China?​
Literature
6 The Cases:​ Potentials and Opportunities of Russian Strategic Innovations “Urbi, Orbi et

Universum”
6.​1 Introduction
6.​2 Agrofood:​ Grain, Food Chain and Brain
6.​3 Aerospace:​ Heroic Past and Heroic Future?​
6.​3.​1 Go-Around
6.​3.​2 Takeoff:​ Growing into the Sky
6.​3.​3 Beyond the Cloud:​ Space Race as Money Maker


6.​4 Far Eastern Federal University (FEFU):​ Vladivostok Valorization
6.​4.​1 Past Successes, Rankings and New Opportunities
6.​4.​2 Building Quadruple Helix
6.​4.​3 FEFU as Strategic Innovation
Literature


© Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2017
Taco C.R. van Someren and Shuhua van Someren-Wang, Strategic Innovation in Russia, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-41081-4_1

1. The Challenge: Renewal of the Russian Innovation
System
Taco C. R. van Someren1 and Shuhua van Someren-Wang1
(1) Ynnovate, Hilversum, The Netherlands

1.1 Strategic Innovation Replaces Technology
Strategic innovation will replace technology competition in the worldwide race for growth and
development.1 In this book it is advocated that Russia should abandon the chase for technology.
Instead Russia should focus on the creation of growth cycles by means of strategic innovation. In the
past decade Russia, like many other countries, has been following the trend of technology creation
often inspired by successes like Silicon Valley, BMW, Toyota, Samsung, Alibaba, Google and

Apple. But in our opinion the future of Russia is depending on strategic innovation and not merely on
technical innovations. Strategic innovation is the future of Russia.
Russia has the potential to become one of the top players in the world innovation league. In
history, Russian people have already proven to be great inventors, creative problem solvers,
perseverant and flexible leaders. Among others, all these characteristics are needed to be successful
innovators. The great strength of Russia is its people. And innovation is people’s business, not
technology. Culturally, Russia is people oriented which is the greatest asset in future world economy.
But a true revolutionary change in perspective is necessary to unleash Russia’s innovation potential
and to overcome current bottlenecks and grasp opportunities. Innovation is not technology but human
being driven business which fits perfectly to Russia. Hence, success needs more than invention and
breakthrough technology, it needs strategic innovation to create new enterprises, industries, create a
prosperous Russia and change the world economy. Russia needs a mind shift from pure technology to
including human being and non-technological oriented strategic innovations.
But what do we exactly mean by strategic innovation? Strategic innovation is about creating new
business based on technical and non-technical innovations followed by growth, development,
employment and prosperity (Someren, 2005, 2015b; Someren & Someren-Wang, 2012, 2013b).
Strategic innovation is not about following hypes on technology, management techniques or policies.
To understand the relevance of strategic innovation in relation to the knowledge economy Table 1.1
shows the case of economic value of knowledge in relation to academic professors, politicians and
football players in the United Kingdom.2
Table 1.1 Value of education, politics and football


Sources data: BBC News Magazine; English Football Wages: 1984 to 2010 by Ahmed Bilal on
October 31, 2011
One has to be careful how to phrase the following comparison, but in general and on average, the
educational level and state of the art knowledge of professors is the highest followed by prime
minister and football players at the lower end. Around 1980 the differences between income levels
were more or less in the same league. About 30 years later, a complete different situation emerged.
Firstly, the football players were by far the highest income earners followed by a sharp increase of

smart politicians. The most professors focused on teaching, doing research and writing Apublications lagged behind. Secondly, it appears that average income was exactly opposite from
educational level and cutting edge knowledge. Before the 1980s most football players were amateurs
and had to earn money after their career on the pitch by opening a cigar store requiring no knowledge
at all. Decades later they are top earners in very early life and multi-millionaire. What has happened
in these three decades?
Strategic innovations explain the difference in value creation, growth, development and becoming
unique. Again the explanation does not come from technology. In the world of football, some smart
creative people started to professionalize and commercialize the football game. New markets were
created by selling merchandise such as shirts. More importantly, new alliances with business parties
from the entertainment industry were formed. TV rights of national leagues were sold to public and
private TV stations. The success was dependent on the creativity of the individual player, the success
of a team and the attractiveness of a league or tournament. Politicians also followed the principle of
strategic innovation but not as successful as the football players. The football players indeed created
a new industry and an extraordinary entertainment value. Politicians did not create a new market or
even industry but they created a personal market by valorizing their experiences by selling memoires,
becoming advisor or giving dinner speeches and high fees in return. Politicians are not valorizing
good knowledge or good decisions, even bad decisions or wrong judgments are being paid as long as
the public gets excitement back or a view behind the scenes. They are selling excitement and political


thriller situations and not excellent strategic insight or new knowledge. Professors need large sums of
money to carry out laboratory experiments, they write difficult articles requiring a large time
investment for a very small audience which has no value for the big public. Only excellent research
for the happy few gets published. Publishing your results costs money and the publisher earns the big
money by selling the reviewed journals. Professors get famous but not rich. Only those professors
who were able to transform their knowledge into new ventures had chances to valorize their newly
created knowledge.
Therefore, it is not the knowledge economy that will determine the next decades but entrepreneurs
who are able to create strategic innovations. An example of such hype is the Knowledge Economy.
The knowledge economy states that the future key production factor is knowledge mostly embedded in

new technologies. McDonald’s hamburger case demonstrates that without technology or knowledge a
billion dollar business can be built and which is hard to imitate. The hamburger case is revealing.
Everybody of us is able to cook a hamburger. Even if you are not a very good cook, you can learn it
within a half day. There is no technology or specific knowledge involved. But there is one American
who made a multibillion dollar business out of the hamburger. The long time success and profitability
of the entrepreneur McKroc, who founded McDonald’s, could hardly be copied by its competitors.
How to explain this success of an apparently easy to copy business case? The solution is definitely
not to be found in technology or special knowledge. There is something more than technology.
Strategic innovation is the continuous process of creating and developing growth cycles by using
the interaction in time between technical and non-technical innovations (Someren, 1991, 2005;
Someren & Someren-Wang, 2012, 2013b). Examples of strategic innovations are the standardized
hamburger by McDonald’s, the supermarket, the Just-In-Time (JIT) manufacturing principle, the
IKEA reversed construction by customers, Star Wars movie and its battle between good against bad,
Silicon Valley as a region and the bitcoin. It is the secret of strategic innovation explains the success
and potential for growth and development. Strategic innovation is beyond technology, beyond new
business models and beyond smart policies. Strategic innovation is at the core of the emergence of
new firms, new industries, new regions and growth of development of nations worldwide.

1.2 The Relevance of Strategic Innovation for Russia
The current starting position of Russia in the worldwide economy is not very favorable. There are
many reasons why strategic innovation should be the core issue for Russia in the near future. We only
give a few reasons without having the pretention to be complete or comprehensive. But already these
arguments are sufficient to adopt and apply strategic innovation approach in Russia.

1.2.1 Not Diversification but Renewal of Domestic Industries Is Key
Contrary to mainstream analysis, opinions and media, Russia’s economy is not dependent on natural
resources. In Table 1.2 the apparent dependency, also in comparison to other countries, becomes
clear.
Table 1.2 Contribution of natural resources to gross domestic product
Country


Azerbaijan

Total natural resources
rents
% of GDP 2013
36.4

Oil rents
% of GDP
2013
33.9

Natural gas
rents
% of GDP 2013
2.3

Coal rents
% of GDP
2013
0.0

Mineral rents
% of GDP
2013
0.2

Forest rents
% of GDP

2013
0.0


Canada
China

5.1
4.5

4.0
1.2

0.0
0.1

0.1
1.1

0.7
1.8

0.4
0.3

Russian
Federation

18.2


13.7

2.0

0.7

1.2

0.5

United States

1.2

0.9

0.0

0.1

0.1

0.1

Source data: 2015 World Development Indicators, table 3.15
National resources in Russia contribute 18.2 % to GDP (2013) which is indeed relatively high
compared to other world countries. In 2013 the share of oil and gas export (excluding other natural
resources) in GDP is 68 % (Metelitsa, 2014). This appears to confirm the picture in the media and
even some scientific publications presenting Russia as an economy dependent on natural resources.
But this media picture and academic parrot behavior is not true because more than 80 % of Russian

GDP comes from other sectors than natural resources such as manufacturing, retail, IT, telecom, real
estate, construction, transport and finance. The oil and gas industry delivers about half of Russia’s
governmental total tax income. The relative and absolute high portion of natural resources exports in
GDP exports demonstrates a lack of internationalization of the non-resources industries. Hence, a
tremendous potential for internationalization is present.
But first innovation capability has to be increased resulting in higher competitiveness and
enhanced diversification as a prerequisite for internationalization. In Russia all industries in the
economy are present but they need to be reinvented in order to take next steps towards innovation
powerhouses, world class competitiveness and ultimately global presence. These other than
resources industries do have a large potential for strategic innovation.
Strategic innovation revolutionizes the future of Russia towards growth and development. In this
respect, Russia could even increase the rents produced on e.g. minerals and forestry by developing
added value activities on top of extracting natural resources. A move upward the value chain would
be the result. In Russia some steps into this direction have been made. The past decade showed the
emergence of incubators, Triple Helix structures, innovation centers and innovation policies. But
despite the huge amount of investments in the technology orientated and dominated programs did not
yet show bottom line results. The reason is, as we will demonstrate later on, that some critical
aspects of strategic innovation have not paid attention to.

1.2.2 Future World Society
There are manifold developments changing the future economy and we only present some illustrations
(e.g. Someren, 2015b; Someren & Someren-Wang, 2012, 2013b). One of the most profound
developments is the growth of world population and its growing diversity. Included developments are
migration, shifting mix between young and old, rich and poor, urbanization and city economies force
to rethink function and operation of (mega) cities, regions and nations as a whole. Any organization
will be confronted with these and other developments. Possible consequences are for example, a
changing client base with different needs or a work force featured by a larger diversity with
implications for leadership and ultimately innovation.
Of course new technologies are another relevant reason for Russia to rethink their economy. Well
known general categories of technology are, among many others, digitalization, renewable energy,

biotechnology and nanotechnology. But most of these fields are still in their infancy and their impacts
are at the moment hard to judge and to oversee. An alternative view is to think in issues to be solved


like obesities and ageing requiring (technical) solutions.
The current globalized world is a Western dominated world. Globalization is an economic system
invented by large American and West-European multinationals. Globalization is a cost saving system
outsourcing functions like manufacturing, administration and after sales to low cost countries. This
short term based system is focused on reducing costs and achieving economies of scale and scope.
With the rise of other countries, globalization with Western enterprises at the core will dwindle.

1.2.3 Sustainability
The current linear directed value chains are characterized by detrimental social and ecological
effects. Consequently, issues like climate change, CO2 emissions, scarcity of some natural resources
and biodiversity were largely neglected by the globalization movement of the past decades. In Russia
sustainability is not a hot issue yet. Nevertheless, sustainability will be at the core of the future global
long growth till the twenty-second century (Someren, 1995; Someren & Someren-Wang, 2012).
Very long value chains supported by cheap modes of transport and distribution are a complex
system of many different parties. In this classical industrial organization, these parties are needed for
the primary process of production and the secondary service processes. For example, long food
chains with global reach and numerous involved parties deliver the end product to the consumer.
The linear production process does not take into account issues of recycling, emission and other
environmental or social effects. This leads to another profound change of our economy being
sustainability in every aspect of our industrial organization.
The linear mode of manufacturing will be substituted by the circular economy. The circular
economy will be accompanied by new firms, new industries and new behavior on markets. Examples
are the renewable energy market, new propulsion concepts for automotive and aerospace sector and
recycling industries. Sustainability is characterized by long life cycles.
The long term consequence of sustainability is in sharp contrast with the short life cycles of some
services of the Internet of Things industry. Hence, in the future economy we have to deal with this

paradox of simultaneous existence of short term and long term time effects.

1.2.4 Geopolitical Power Shifts
In the era of globalization, the Cold War showed the main players of that old time: the Atlantic
alliance and Russia and its allies. In the coming decades new potential extreme powerful players
enter the world scene. Already in the globalization era, the rise of the so-called BRICS (Brazil,
Russia, India, China and South Africa) countries was foreseen. But after a promising start of these
countries it appeared that getting into the highest league of economic high performers needed more
than a decade of double digit growth based on infrastructure investments and resource exploitation.
The biggest challenge for these countries is innovation in every aspect of the economy which needs
much more than R&D investments, technology programs and Silicon Valley copycat regions
(Someren, 2015a, b). They all need strategic innovation which requires much more than copycat
technology or improvements. Moreover, other countries with high economic ambitions also entered
the arena like Indonesia, several Arabic countries and Turkey. Of all countries, China seems to be the
most promising and best contender of existing world class players like USA and some countries from
the EU.
For Russia, the relationship with China is a special case with a long history. Not only for the
regions along borderline in the Russian Far East but for Russia as a whole, the relationship with


China will be pivotal in the future. There are huge opportunities but also huge risks. The sanctions
initiated by US and EU against Russia awakened the Russian economic bear. The logical and still
profitable relation with the EU has been cut off, or at least has been put on ice, forcing Russia to turn
their head to the East. The sanctions were in fact a wakeup call for Russia to invest in their own
production capacity instead of relying on imports. For the Chinese, the timing could not be better.
After decades of growth and development, the demand for land, energy and basic research is
enormous. Closer relationships between Russia and China seem to have a win-win effect but only
under specific conditions dictated by strategic innovation. As we will see later on, in most cases
these conditions are not yet fulfilled. As long as this situation continues, the win for Russia is not very
likely.


1.2.5 Market Economy quo vadis?!
The free market economy in the real sense of the notion as rational participants with free will and
decision power has only existed in economic text books. In the capitalistic and market economy many
distortions diluted the free market economy such as monopolization of markets, power concentration,
externalization of costs such as ecological detrimental effects, alliances between private enterprises,
governments and financial crisis like in financial crisis and so on. Oil and gas market power of OPEC
during 1980s and Gazprom are well known and they used power to set prices and have power over
energy supplies. Now Google, Facebook, governments, platforms, and banks own Big Data and have
power over demand and behavior of individuals and the user is left with empty hands.
Furthermore, the text book market economy was based on Western Europe and US context and
situations. The market governance in many other emerging countries does not fit to textbook
economics. Russia, China and African countries have different market principles. In Russia,
government is often identical with market, in the EU government is both a very large market
participant as well as shaper of market conditions and in China a market system with Chinese
characteristics is being created. Now emerging regions and other countries gain economic power, the
market economy in its current form will disappear and be replaced by another system fitting to the
future world growth curve dominated by emerging parties. Strong linkages and other forms of
symbiosis between private enterprises and governments create a different ‘market economy’.
On the macroeconomic level also long term potential changes will rock the fundaments of the
market economy. For example, the US is able to exert market power because the dollar is the
dominant currency in international trade. Dollar transactions and its clearing through American
banking system gives the US the possibility to sanction or fine certain transactions and defend
American interests. How will the world look like when the Chinese Renminbi takes over the role of
the dollar?
The answer to all of these examples of major developments, only strategic innovations and not
technological innovation provide the right answer to these profound changes. A new world order will
emerge (Someren, 2015b; Someren & Someren-Wang, 2012, 2013b, c, d). Before we elaborate on
this central core issue we first have to understand Russian current situation and its historical path to
the present.


1.3 Russian Heroic but Unknown Innovation History
Russia has a great history in innovation of which most are not aware. But as everywhere, there are


ups and downs in the output and impact of the innovations. In Fig. 1.1 a few examples of great
inventions demonstrate the high capability of Russian innovators.
In several industries from agro food sector to space technologies, some radical inventions such as
caterpillar, radio, television, airliner, firefighting foam and nuclear energy are of Russian origin. Of
course, almost any country can produce such a list of inventions with high impact. Most of the time
these lists are dominated by new technologies or some physical object. Much more important from an
economic point of view is however, the ability to establish and grow new enterprises and new
industries. Then the list with famous inventions is not important anymore. More relevant becomes the
ability to create a context to transform an invention into an innovation. The innovation is the
commercialization of a (technical) invention. As soon as this hurdle of first market introduction has
been taken the next challenge is to grow this venture. All over the world this is still one of the key
issues of innovation management. It is also a key issue of the current Russian economy but such a
context or environment fostering innovation is largely absent. The examples of Russian inventions in
Fig. 1.1 exactly demonstrate this omission. There are no Russian world class TV manufacturers,
Russian airline manufacturers are not able to compete with top notch manufacturers, solar cell
technology is commercialized by German, American, Chinese and Japanese manufacturers and space
industry knowledge is not applied commercially.
This failing ability to commercialize is not a sudden problem but the result of a historical process
with regard to innovation. In the Russian communist era to achieve certain production quantities
levels determined by the state were at the core of the total system. Agriculture, mining and heavy
industry were believed to be the main pillars of the economy. For innovation was no place. This
period of state planning, production and distribution was followed by a glasnost period in which
regulation by the state and state planning was left over to a few players. This development lead to
(local) industrial concentration and wealth accumulation limited to an inner circle. Again wealth
accumulation and distribution was far more important than innovation. Soon after this bonanza, state

leaders came to the conclusion that technology should be at the core of future wealth and prosperity.
Now innovation is on the radar of the governmental leaders. However, it still largely misses a
breeding ground because of history and everything has to be built up from scratch. In recent times, the
Russian economy is on the brink of trying to catch up with world leading companies and countries.
Although wide spread innovation is absent in the past decades of Russian history, it does not mean
Russian innovative activity was completely neglected. On the contrary, some governmental programs,
like conquering space, require a bunch of innovations. Furthermore, education and basic research
were on a quite high level. But hampered by institutional structures, the basic research and high level
education did not get the opportunity to flow into commercial products and services for Russian
markets or exports. For the remainder of this chapter we focus on the past decades of innovation
development in Russia.

1.4 Current Status of Innovation in the Russian Economy
Strategic innovation leads to world class innovation competence, global powerhouses and
international top competiveness. The most eye-catching key characteristic of the recent Russian
economy is the relatively high dependency on natural resources in exports and the low innovation rate
in other industries. But there are more typical factors explaining the current difficulties of the failing
growth and development of the Russian economy. These factors are insufficient innovation
performance, insufficient internationalization, insufficient entrepreneurial activity and insufficient


contribution of private SMEs.

1.4.1 Insufficient Innovation Performance
Governments are interested in the number and scope of their new policies but show low concern
about their implementation, effectiveness, results and impacts. We are mainly interested in their
bottom line results. Innovation without added value and impact is lost effort. Therefore, we have to
look at the current status of innovation in Russia.
Innovation cannot be caught in a single figure or measurement representing the state of innovation
economy. For this reason, we took in Table 1.3 some well-known and generally accepted indices to

show the position of Russia in the recent years.
Table 1.3 A few key data Russian economy
Measure
R&D expenditure % of GDP

%
1

Year
2009

1.5

2013

% of Russian firms involved in innovation

10 %

Share of government investment R&D

66–75 % 2010–2014

Global competitiveness (The World Economic Forum)

Rank Trend

2008/2009 51
2012/2013 67
2013/2014 64

2014/2015 53

Globalisation index (A. T. Kearney Foreign Policy Magazine)

Global Innovation Quotient (R&D related, Bloomberg)

Global Innovation Index (innovation level of countries, INSEAD, WIPO)

The European Innovation Scoreboard (European Commission)

2007

31

2010

42

2013

48

2013

14

2014

18


2015

14

2007

54

2012

32

2013

62

2014

49

2011

7

2013

9

2014


9

Sources data: RVC (2013, 2014, 2015); The Future of Russia’s Innovation Economy. No. 6,
September 2014. p. 9; European Commission, http://​www.​gks.​ru/​wps/​wcm/​connect/​rosstat_​main/​
rosstat/​ru/​statistics/​science_​and_​innovations/​science/​
In Table 1.3 a common index of innovation activity is the percentage of GDP spent on R&D. For
Russia the R&D expenditure has risen from 1 % in 2009 to 1.5 % in 2013. This is a hopeful sign but
R&D is not a measurement of innovation (the commercial product or service) but only of potential
invention or prototype. Moreover, R&D is not a measurement of non-technical innovation at all.
Nevertheless, whatever restrictions can be made about this indicator the upward trend cannot be


denied. However, the rankings should be considered critically because most innovation indices focus
on input factors, R&D, education or scientific papers as output (e.g. Edquist & Zabala-Iturriagagoitia,
2015). From the perspective of strategic innovation, only dynamic value, growth and development
would be the real measure (Someren, 1991; Someren & Someren-Wang, 2013b).
What is more revealing about the state of the Russian economy with regard to innovation is the
number of Russian firms involved in innovation. For Russia about 10 % of all firms are involved in
innovation. This fits to the share of governmental investments in R&D which is between 66 and 75 %
in the period 2010 till 2014. When measuring Russia along a few indexes, Table 1.3 shows a clear
trend. According to the Globalisation Index, the role of Russia in the global economy is decreasing.
Although the Global Competitiveness Index indicates a slight improvement in 2013/2014, other
indices seem to confirm the revolving up and downward trend of Russia. In the ranking of the Global
Innovation Quotient, Russia tumbled from rank 14 (2013) to 18 (2014) and back again in three years’
time. In the Global Innovation Index, a short improvement in ranking (2012) was followed by an even
lower position in 2013 compared to 2007 and a small comeback in 2014. The European Innovation
Scoreboard confirms this downtrend in ranking of innovation country performance.
In Fig. 1.2 the Russian position compared to other BRICS and some other countries is presented
measured by the global innovation performance index in the period 2010–2011 (EU, 2014, p. 29).
(Note: Average performance is measured using a composite indicator building on data for 12

indicators ranging from a lowest possible performance of 0 to a maximum possible performance of
1).

Fig. 1.2 Global innovation performance. Source data: EU Scoreboard (2014, fig. 25, p. 29, 2015, fig. 27, p. 32)

In 2011, South Korea with an innovation index of 0.74 is the leader very closely followed by the
United States (0.736) and of the other Asian countries Japan (0.711) is second. The EU (0.63) is
close to this top three. China (0.275) is ahead of all BRICS countries and Russia is lagging behind
with an innovation performance index of 0.191. In 2012, Russia maintained its position with a score
of 0.190 whereas South Korea, US, Australia, Brazil and China improved their performance.
When comparing Russia and China on policy measures, some differences in choices are based on
history of being a plan economy and different insights concerning measures. With regard to Science,


Technology and Innovation policies, Li and Wang (2015) conclude that Russia favors infrastructure
support whereas China adopts policy instruments for administrative support, financial support,
industry and R&D institution collaboration and tax incentives. Furthermore, both Russia and China
implemented Science and Technology policies to stimulate innovation generation. Although the end
goal of becoming an innovative nation did not differ much, the operationalization showed several
differences.
The degree of authority in Russia (‘top down’) was significantly higher than in China (Li & Wang,
2015). Russian policies were predominantly issued by Ministries and bureaus. In Russia about 70 %
of all policies were issued by Ministries. Both countries were keen on commercializing military
technology. But China put more effort in promoting technical transformation of knowledge into
commercial products and generating earnings. Compared to Russia, China implemented twice the
number of policies to stimulate technical transformation. Russia put more effort to absorb new
technologies.
Formally, Russia put more effort in the implementation of innovation into laws by the Duma than
China. To our opinion, this formal implementation rate is not very relevant. More important is the
implementation in economic reality by enterprises and entrepreneurs. Here, the entrepreneurial spirit

of China is far ahead of Russia and contributes to the explanation of the higher innovation
performance.
But being and staying a frontrunner or becoming a serious contender and take over top positions
depends also on the growth rate of innovation over a longer period of time. This innovation growth
rate is shown in Fig. 1.3.

Fig. 1.3 Global innovation growth rates. Source data: EU Scoreboard (2014, fig. 26, p. 29, 2015, fig. 28, p. 32)

Over the time period of 2006 till 2013 the growth rate of South Korea (6.0 %) and China (5.8 %)
is relatively big compared to other countries. Therefore, in the period 2006–2013, South Korea was
able to improve its position against many rival countries. Russia has as the only country in this
benchmark a negative growth of −1.8 %. Due to its higher growth rate, the EU was able to close the


gap with the US and Japan. South Korea, US and Japan do perform well because of indicators
capturing business activity as measured by R&D expenditures in the business sector, public-private
co-publications and PCT patents (EU, 2014, p. 29). However, in the period 2007–2014, Canada and
South Africa joined Russia in the negative growth league but Russia managed to slow down its
negative growth rate. Between 2007 and 2014, only Brazil and India improved their positive
innovation growth rate.
The negative growth rate of Russia is not a single year with an extreme bad performance but an
overall declining situation as Fig. 1.4 reveals.

Fig. 1.4 Innovation performance Russia. Source: EU Scoreboard (2014, p. 39, 2015, p. 40)

Between 2006 and 2013 the average innovation performance of Russia benchmarked against the
EU has dropped gradually each year. Except in 2014, it improved from 30 in 2013 to 31 in 2014.
According to the EU on innovation performance: “The strong decline in 2012 is due to a sharp
decline in new doctorate graduates from 1.4 to 0.4 per 1000 population aged 25–34”…and… “Russia
is performing worse than the EU on 10 indicators, in particular on Public-private copublications,

License and patent revenues from abroad, Patent applications, International copublications and Mostcited publication and Doctorate graduates”. (EU, 2014, p. 28).
With regard to innovation growth performance, Russia is “…Russia’s growth performance is
worse than that of the EU with growth in 10 indicators being below that of the EU, especially for
Doctorate graduates, International copublications, R&D expenditures in the business sector, Patent
applications and License and patent revenues from abroad. Growth was above that of the EU in R&D
expenditures in the public sector and Exports of knowledge-intensive services.” (EU, 2014, p. 39). In
2015 the same conclusion was drawn (EU, 2015, p. 40).
Despite this downward trend on innovation there are certainly some positive signals. In the IT
sector several start-ups in high tech demonstrate the willingness and entrepreneurial sparks in Russia
society. Because of sanctions, in the agro food sector the strive for self-sufficiency replaces the
import of food stuff like tomatoes. However, in this stage the main priority is to install production
capacity and innovation is not yet a core issue.

1.4.2 Insufficient Internationalization


1.4.2 Insufficient Internationalization
For Russia not diversification is the key issue but, firstly, renewal of existing private and public
enterprises, secondly, creation of new industries, and thirdly, internationalization. From Table 1.1 we
have learned that the share of natural resources in GDP is above average but that still more than 80 %
of GDP is earned in other than natural resources sector. Contrary to mainstream economic analysis,
from the perspective of strategic innovation there is no real big diversification problem but an
innovation and internationalization issue. The only way out is, firstly, to renew existing industries,
secondly, to create new industries and new enterprises, and thirdly, to internationalize all industries.
The first two steps are necessary conditions for a successful conquering of world markets and a
diversification of the export portfolio. Strategic innovation leads to a broadening and diversification
of industries and not the other way around. Existing enterprises need to be reinvented, entrepreneurs
should not only start new ventures but also formulate a growth path.
Russia possesses large quantities of natural resources ranging from fresh water, land, minerals,
oil and gas. Contrary to most other resources, particularly oil and gas have been successfully

commercialized and the Russian oil and gas exports fed the treasury in the Kremlin to a very high
extent. However, even for oil and gas the main activity is exploration, mining and selling the crude oil
and gas resources. Knowledge for exploration is often supplied by foreign partners like BP and Shell.
Internationalization of Russian enterprises requires a lower dependency on foreign partners and a
reinvention of exploration activities and a global presence. Moreover, except from extraction often
higher added value activities based on natural resources are rather underdeveloped. Hence, the value
chain potential is not developed very well. The recent plunging crude oil prices due to American
shale gas, the reentering of Iran on the market and the flexible high production levels of Saudi Arabia
in particular confronted Russia with the downside of the oil and gas bonanza. For all the other natural
resources the value chain has the potential to be explored and exploited to a much greater extent. For
example, the fishing and forest industries offer huge opportunities waiting for exploration,
exploitation and internationalization.
Innovating and diversifying the economy is everyone’s advice. But how? It is easy to write a
White Paper or a Policy to create new industries but these kinds of papers never say how to do it or
only in very general terms with no practical value. It is an extremely difficult challenge and there are
no standard recipes. What works in country A is not necessarily a solution for country B. What we do
know is that innovation is inevitable and should be somehow part of the solution. But here again the
awkward question “How?” is at the table. As we will see, in the past decades Russia has issued
several policies, programs and invested huge sums of money into innovation.

1.4.3 Insufficient Entrepreneurial Activity
It does not always require innovation to earn money. But creation of value needs entrepreneurial
activity. In the past decades, the Chinese showed how to make huge amounts of money with ‘copypaste’ and ‘imitate-improve-emulate approaches’ combined with low cost labor manufacturing,
export and increasingly large home market. In Table 1.4 the entrepreneurial activity in different stages
in Russia compared with some other different countries in 2014 are compared.
Table 1.4 Phases of entrepreneurial activity in the GEM economies in 2014 (% of population aged 18–64)
Country Nascent
New business
(2014) entrepreneurship ownership rate
rate

Brazil
3.7
13.8

Early-stage
Entrepreneurial activity
(TEA)
17.2

Established business Discontinuation of
ownership rate
businesses (% of TEA)
17.5

4.1


China

5.4

10.2

15.5

11.6

1.4

Germany 3.1


2.3

5.3

5.2

1.7

India

4.1

2.5

6.6

3.7

1.2

Russia

2.4

2.4

4.7

3.9


1.2

South
Africa

3.9

3.2

7.0

2.7

3.9

United
States

9.7

4.3

13.8

6.9

4.0

Source data: GEM (2014, Table 2.4, pp. 35–37)

In Table 1.4 the entrepreneurial activity along the growth cycle (from start to discontinuation) is
presented. Compared to the US, Brazil and China, the entrepreneurial activity is relatively low. The
low indicator for entrepreneurial activity is result of capability, situation and (perceived)
opportunity. But it is also result of Russian policies to favor imitation strategy carried out by large
incumbent firms and national champions knowing their way in Russian sources for financing (EBRD,
2012, p. 68).
Hence, value creation based on a non-technical basis can be very rewarding in an emerging
country situation. But then also other elements of competition besides innovative capacity become
relevant.
One of these issues of non-technical innovation is branding and creating world brand names. In
Table 1.5 the top world brand names are listed including all Russian brand names and values in the
top 500 ranking positions.
Table 1.5 Global top 500 Brands 2015
Brand name
Apple

Rank 2015 Rank 2014 Industry
1
1
Technology

Country Brand value ($M) 2015 Brand value ($M) 2014
US
128,303
104,680

Samsung

2


2

Conglomerate S. Korea 81,716

78,752

Google

3

3

Technology

US

76,683

68,620

Microsoft

4

4

Technology

US


67,060

62,783

Verizon

5

5

Telecom

US

59,843

53,466

AT&T

6

7

Telecom

US

58,820


45,410

Amazon.com

7

8

Technology

US

56,124

45,147

General Electric 8

6

Technology

US

48,019

52,533

China Mobile


9

13

Telecom

China

47,916

31,845

Walmart

10

9

Retail

US

46,737

44,779
















Sberbank

141

106

Banks

Russia

8668

10,950

Gazprom

178

129


Oil and Gas

Russia

6961

9117

Magnit

313

315

Retail

Russia

4526

4291

MTS

373

406

Telecoms


Russia

3977

3613

Lukoil

417

306

Oil and Gas

Russia

3665

4435

Megafon

486

470

Telecom

Russia


3200

3162

Source data: Global 500, 2015, The annual report on the world’s most valuable global brands,
February 2015


Brand names and trademarks are an expression of the ability to commercialize new or existing
ideas, products or services. They are not necessarily a measure of innovation but innovation can be
the major content of the brand or trade mark. From Table 1.5 it becomes clear that for consumer
technologies a great brand name is linked to success. But also retailers with a famous brand name like
Walmart are able to belong to the top 10 ranked brand names. Even China Mobile achieved rank 9
based on a large home market. The top six Russian brand names are far below on the brand value and
position rankings. Most of the top Russian brands lose value from 2014 to 2015. The rather poor
performance of Russia on brand value is caused by the underdeveloped integration into the world
economy, the low innovation capabilities and low commercialization and valorization competences
across industries.
The trend in brand value is confirmed by the general trend on trademark creation. In Fig. 1.5 the
number of trademarks are compared between Russia, US, China and Benelux.

Fig. 1.5 Trends in number of trademarks in Russia, Benelux, US and China. Source: based on Someren and Someren-Wang (2013, Fig.
4.9, p. 128)

The US is able to constantly create and add new trademarks into the domestic and world
economy. After a slow start in the 1990s, China has emulated the US by creating even more
trademarks after 2005. In sharp contrast to these two contenders, Russia is lagging behind with a
relatively very low increase of number of trademarks. It reflects the low entrepreneurial activity in
Russian economy.
In a market economy, for stock companies, the market capitalization, the value on the stock

market, is the ultimate measure of successful business. Or not? Table 1.6 presents the market cap as
of on 2 February 2016.
Table 1.6 Stock value world top 10
Rank Company
1
Alphabet

Industry
Conglomerate, IT

Market cap in billion $ (02.02.2016) 12 months change on 02.02.16 (%)
537
+46.7


2

Apple

IT

524

−20.4

3

Microsoft

IT


419

+28.4

4

Facebook

IT

326

+52.8

5

Berkshire
Hathaway

Investment

312

−13.7

6

Exxon Mobile


Oil and Gas

311

−16.7

7

Johnson & Johnson Medical, Pharma,
Consumer

290

+2.6

8

General Electric

Technology and Finance

275

+16.6

9

Amazon

IT


260

+51.5

10

Wells Fargo

Banking

249

−7.5

Source data: http://​www.​dogsofthedow.​com/​largest-companies-by-market-cap.​htm
The first impression from Table 1.5 is the dominance of well-known IT enterprises like Alphabet
(the mother company of Google). However, from the perspective of strategic innovation, market cap
rankings should be taken with care for several reasons. Firstly, the market caps are daily values and
vulnerable for unexpected external and internal events. For example, VW plummeted after the diesel
gate. Only because of oil price decrease, the former leading market caps such as Shell and Exxon
disappeared from the top ten. Secondly, although market value is based on net present value of
expected profits, the long term value creation capability could look differently. Apple dropped down
the list due to doubts on future innovative products. Thirdly, what’s behind the figures? Alphabet is
Google plus new ventures. Google’s revenues are for about 90 % dependent on advertisements
(Vijayan, 2015). Most of Google’s other ventures are future investments in other sectors without
value contribution. Fourthly, other industries like natural resources are dependent on commodity
markets and world economic outlook. But still, these industries do have good prospects for value
chain activities and cross over industries. Fifthly, the top ten does not reflect the entire economy. On
the contrary, even the lower regions of the top 2000, there are many other industries and smaller

market cap enterprises, the hidden champions, which can form the true solid backbone of an economy.
Therefore, for Russia there are still opportunities in IT but other sectors as well which fit to the
country’s profile and strengths.

1.4.4 Insufficient Contribution of SMEs
In most countries like US, EU and China the SME sector plays a significant role in market dynamics
and particularly innovation. The Russian definition of SME is comparable to criteria used in EU. The
federal law #209-FZ “On small and medium business development in the Russian Federation”
defines SMES as, firstly, the ownership structure, the SME’s stake held by one or several legal
entities, which are not small or medium businesses, should not exceed 25 %; secondly, workforce, the
number of employees should not exceed 250 people, and thirdly, volume of revenue, the annual
turnover should not exceed 25 million euros (Federal web portal for small and medium sized
enterprises in Russia, 2015). In the period between 2008 and 2012, Russia’s private sector lost
300,000 jobs while the state added 1.1 million workers to public companies.
The contribution of SMEs in the EU is on average of 40 % of GDP in Russia SMEs contribute just
15 %. Nevertheless, since 2005 the role of SMEs in Russia, in number and turnover, has steadily
grown by almost 30 % from 3.4 million to 4.4 million in 2012 (EIB, 2013, p. 9). The number of


×